Suppose that Yves and Zoe are neighbouring farmers, both of whom grow organic tomatoes. Both sell their output to the same grocery store chains that carry organic foods; so, in a real sense, Yves and Zoe compete with each other.
Does this mean that Yves should try to stop Zoe from growing tomatoes or that Yves and Zoe should form an agreement to grow less? Almost certainly not: there are hundreds or thousands of organic tomato farmers, and Yves and Zoe are competing with all those other growers as well as with each other. Because so many farmers sell organic tomatoes, if any one of them produced more or less, there would be no measurable effect on market prices.
When people talk about business competition, the image they often have in mind is a situation in which two or three rival firms are intensely struggling for advantage. But economists know that when an industry consists of a few main competitors, it’s actually a sign that competition is fairly limited. As the example of organic tomatoes suggests, when there is enough competition, it doesn’t even make sense to identify your rivals: there are so many competitors that you cannot single out any one of them as a rival.
A price-taking producer is a producer whose actions have no effect on the market price of the good or service it sells.
We can put it another way: Yves and Zoe are price-taking producers. A producer is a price-
A price-taking consumer is a consumer whose actions have no effect on the market price of the good or service he or she buys.
A perfectly competitive market is a market in which all market participants are price-
In a perfectly competitive market, all market participants, both consumers and producers, are price-
The supply and demand model, which we introduced in Chapter 3 and have used repeatedly since then, is a model of a perfectly competitive market. It depends fundamentally on the assumption that the actions of an individual buyer or seller of a good, such as coffee beans or organic tomatoes, cannot affect the price at which he or she can buy or sell the good.
A perfectly competitive industry is an industry in which all producers are price-
As a general rule, consumers are indeed price-
Under what circumstances will all producers be price-
The markets for major grains, like wheat and corn, are perfectly competitive: individual wheat and corn farmers, as well as individual buyers of wheat and corn, take market prices as given. In contrast, the markets for some of the food items made from these grains—
A producer’s market share is the fraction of the total industry output accounted for by that producer’s output.
First, for an industry to be perfectly competitive, it must contain many producers, none of whom have a large market share. A producer’s market share is the fraction of the total industry output accounted for by that producer’s output. The distribution of market share constitutes a major difference between the grain industry and the breakfast cereal industry. There are thousands of wheat farmers, none of whom account for more than a tiny fraction of total wheat sales.
The breakfast cereal industry, however, is dominated by four producers: Kellogg’s, General Mills, Post Foods, and the Quaker Oats Company. Kellogg’s alone accounts for more than 40% of all cereal sales. Kellogg’s executives know that if they try to sell more cornflakes, they are likely to drive down the market price of cornflakes. That is, they know that their actions influence market prices, simply because they are so large a part of the market that changes in their production will significantly affect the overall quantity supplied. It makes sense to assume that producers are price-
Second, an industry can be perfectly competitive only if consumers regard the products of all producers as equivalent. This clearly isn’t true in the breakfast cereal market: Cap’n Crunch isn’t considered a good substitute for Multi Grain Cheerios. As a result, the maker of Multi Grain Cheerios has some ability to increase its price without fear that it will lose all its customers to the maker of Cap’n Crunch.
A good is a standardized product, also known as a commodity, when consumers regard the products of different producers as the same good.
Contrast this with the case of a standardized product, which is a product that consumers regard as the same good even when it comes from different producers, sometimes known as a commodity. Because wheat is a standardized product,1 consumers regard the output of one wheat producer as a perfect substitute for that of another producer. Consequently, one farmer cannot increase the price for his or her wheat without losing all sales to other wheat farmers. So the second necessary condition for a competitive industry is that the industry output is a standardized product (see the upcoming For Inquiring Minds).
All perfectly competitive industries have many producers with small market shares, producing a standardized product. Most perfectly competitive industries are also characterized by one more feature: it is easy for new firms to enter the industry or for firms that are currently in the industry to leave. That is, no obstacles in the form of government regulations or limited access to key resources prevent new producers from entering the market. And no additional costs are associated with shutting down a company and leaving the industry. Economists refer to the arrival of new firms into an industry as entry; they refer to the departure of firms from an industry as exit. When there are no obstacles to entry into or exit from an industry, we say that the industry has free entry and exit. For example, in the convenience store market, the set-up cost of a corner shop is relatively low, which allows owners to enter and leave the market easily.
An industry has free entry and exit when new producers can easily enter into an industry and existing producers can easily leave that industry.
Free entry and exit is not strictly necessary for perfect competition. In Chapter 5 we described the case of lobster fishing in Atlantic Canada, where regulations limit the number of licences and thus lobster traps, so entry into the industry is limited. Despite this, there are enough boats operating that the fishers are price-takers. But free entry and exit is a key factor in most competitive industries. It ensures that the number of producers in an industry can adjust to changing market conditions. And, in particular, it ensures that producers in an industry cannot act to keep new firms out. To sum up, then, perfect competition depends on two necessary conditions. First, the industry must contain many producers, each having a small market share. Second, the industry must produce a standardized product. In addition, perfectly competitive industries are normally characterized by free entry and exit.
A perfectly competitive industry must produce a standardized product. But is it enough for the products of different firms actually to be the same? No: people must also think that they are the same. And producers often go to great lengths to convince consumers that they have a distinctive, or differentiated, product, even when they don’t.
Consider, for example, champagne—not the super-expensive premium champagnes but the more ordinary stuff. Most people cannot tell the difference between champagne actually produced in the Champagne region of France, where the product originated, and similar products from Spain, British Columbia, or Ontario. But the French government has sought and obtained legal protection for the winemakers of Champagne, ensuring that around the world only bubbly wine from that region can be called champagne. If it’s from someplace else, all the seller can do is say that it was produced using the méthode Champenoise. This creates a differentiation in the minds of consumers and lets the champagne producers of Champagne charge higher prices.
Similarly, Korean producers of kimchi, the spicy fermented cabbage that is the Korean national side dish, are doing their best to convince consumers that the same product packaged by Japanese firms is just not the real thing. The purpose is, of course, to ensure higher prices for Korean kimchi.
So is an industry perfectly competitive if it sells products that are indistinguishable except in name but that consumers, for whatever reason, don’t think are standardized? No. When it comes to defining the nature of competition, the consumer is always right.
How does an industry that meets these three criteria behave? As a first step toward answering that question, let’s look at how an individual producer in a perfectly competitive industry maximizes profit.
Sometimes it is possible to see an industry become perfectly competitive. In fact, it happens frequently in the case of pharmaceuticals when the patent on a popular drug expires.
When a company develops a new drug, it is usually able to receive a patent, which gives it a legal monopoly—the exclusive right to sell the drug—for 20 years from the date of filing. Legally, no one else can sell that drug without the patent owner’s permission. When the patent expires, the market is open for other companies to sell their own versions of the drug, known collectively as generics. Generics are standardized products, much like the painkillers ASA and ibuprofen, and are often sold by many producers.
The shift from a market with a single seller to perfect competition, not coincidentally, is accompanied by a sharp fall in the market price. For example, when the patent expired for the painkiller ibuprofen and generics were introduced, its price eventually fell by more than 60%; the price of the painkiller naproxen fell by about 80%. On average, drug prices are 40% lower after a generic enters the market.
Not surprisingly, the makers of patent-protected drugs are eager to forestall the entry of generic competitors and have tried a variety of strategies. A firm applying to Health Canada to market a generic version of a drug must show that it does not infringe on patents filed by brand-name firms. However, brand-name companies can challenge the application, resulting in an automatic 24-month delay. As a result, the original drug maker continues to charge high prices and reap high profits. In the United States, one especially successful tactic is for the original drug maker to make an agreement with a potential generic competitor, essentially paying the competitor to delay its entry into the market. These agreements have been fiercely contested by many government regulators, who view them as anti-competitive practices that hurt consumers. As of the time of writing, drug makers, consumers, and government officials were awaiting a decision by the courts on the legality of these agreements.
Neither the actions of a price-taking producer nor those of a price-taking consumer can influence the market price of a good.
In a perfectly competitive market all producers and consumers are price-takers.
Consumers are almost always price-takers, but this is often not true of producers. An industry in which producers are price-takers is a perfectly competitive industry.
A perfectly competitive industry contains many producers, each of which produces a standardized product (also known as a commodity) but none of which has a large market share.
Most perfectly competitive industries are also characterized by free entry and exit.
CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING 12-1
In each of the following situations, do you think the industry described will be perfectly competitive or not? Explain your answer.
There are two producers of aluminum in the world, a good sold in many places.
The price of natural gas is determined by global supply and demand. A small share of that global supply is produced by a handful of companies located in the North Sea.
Dozens of designers sell high-fashion clothes. Each designer has a distinctive style and a loyal clientele.
There are many NHL teams in North America, one or two in each major city and each selling tickets to its hometown events.
With only two producers in the world, each producer will represent a sizable share of the market. So the industry will not be perfectly competitive.
Because each producer of natural gas from the North Sea has only a small market share of total world supply of natural gas, and since natural gas is a standardized product, the natural gas industry will be perfectly competitive.
Because each designer has a distinctive style, high-fashion clothes are not a standardized product. So the industry will not be perfectly competitive.
The market described here is the market in each city for tickets to NHL games. Since there are only one or two teams in each major city, each team will represent a sizable share of the market. So the industry will not be perfectly competitive.