During a 2004 flu vaccine shortage in the United States, some pharmaceutical distributors believed they could sharply drive up flu vaccine prices because the price elasticity of vaccine demand was small. But what does that mean? How low does a price elasticity have to be for us to classify it as low? How big does it have to be for us to consider it high? And what determines whether the price elasticity of demand is high or low, anyway?
To answer these questions, we need to look more deeply at the price elasticity of demand.
As a first step toward classifying price elasticities of demand, let’s look at the extreme cases.
First, consider the demand for a good when people pay no attention to the price—
Demand is perfectly inelastic when the quantity demanded does not respond at all to changes in the price. When demand is perfectly inelastic, the demand curve is a vertical line.
The opposite extreme occurs when even a tiny rise in the price will cause the quantity demanded to drop to zero or even a tiny fall in the price will cause the quantity demanded to get extremely large.
Demand is perfectly elastic when any price increase will cause the quantity demanded to drop to zero. When demand is perfectly elastic, the demand curve is a horizontal line.
Panel (b) of Figure 6-2 shows the case of pink tennis balls; we suppose that tennis players really don’t care what colour their balls are and that other colours, such as neon green and vivid yellow, are available at $5 per dozen balls. In this case, consumers will buy no pink balls if they cost more than $5 per dozen but will buy only pink balls if they cost less than $5. The demand curve will therefore be a horizontal line at a price of $5 per dozen balls. As you move back and forth along this line, there is a change in the quantity demanded but no change in the price. Roughly speaking, when you divide a number by zero, you get infinity, denoted by the symbol ∞. So a horizontal demand curve implies an infinite price elasticity of demand. When the price elasticity of demand is infinite, economists say that demand is perfectly elastic.
Demand is elastic if the price elasticity of demand is greater than 1, inelastic if the price elasticity of demand is less than 1, and unit-elastic if the price elasticity of demand is exactly 1.
The price elasticity of demand for the vast majority of goods is somewhere between these two extreme cases. Economists use one main criterion for classifying these intermediate cases: they ask whether the price elasticity of demand is greater or less than 1. When the price elasticity of demand is greater than 1, economists say that demand is elastic. When the price elasticity of demand is less than 1, they say that demand is inelastic. The borderline case is unit-elastic demand, where the price elasticity of demand is—
To see why a price elasticity of demand equal to 1 is a useful dividing line, let’s consider a hypothetical example: a toll bridge operated by the provincial ministry of transportation. Other things equal, the number of drivers who use the bridge depends on the toll, the price for crossing the bridge: the higher the toll, the fewer the drivers who use the bridge.
Figure 6-3 shows three hypothetical demand curves—
Panel (a) shows what happens when the toll is raised from $0.90 to $1.10 and the demand curve is unit-
Panel (b) shows a case of inelastic demand when the toll is raised from $0.90 to $1.10. The same 20% price rise reduces the quantity demanded from 1050 to 950. That’s only a 10% decline, so in this case the price elasticity of demand is 10%/20% = 0.5.
Panel (c) shows a case of elastic demand when the toll is raised from $0.90 to $1.10. The 20% price increase causes the quantity demanded to fall from 1200 to 800—a 40% decline, so the price elasticity of demand is 40%/20% = 2.
The total revenue is the total value of sales of a good or service. It is equal to the price multiplied by the quantity sold.
Why does it matter whether demand is unit-
Total revenue has a useful graphical representation that can help us understand why knowing the price elasticity of demand is crucial when we ask whether a price rise will increase or reduce total revenue. Panel (a) of Figure 6-4 shows the same demand curve as panel (a) of Figure 6-3. We see that 1100 drivers will use the bridge if the toll is $0.90. So the total revenue at a price of $0.90 is $0.90 × 1100 = $990.
This value is equal to the area of the green rectangle, which is drawn with the bottom left corner at the point (0, 0) and the top right corner at (1100, 0.90). In general, the total revenue at any given price is equal to the area of a rectangle whose height is the price and whose width is the quantity demanded at that price.
To get an idea of why total revenue is important, consider the following scenario. Suppose that the toll on the bridge is currently $0.90 but that the ministry of transportation must raise extra money for road repairs. One way to do this is to raise the toll on the bridge. But this plan might backfire, since a higher toll will reduce the number of drivers who use the bridge. And if traffic on the bridge dropped a lot, a higher toll would actually reduce total revenue instead of increasing it. So it’s important for the ministry of transportation to know how drivers will respond to a toll increase.
We can see graphically how the toll increase affects total bridge revenue by examining panel (b) of Figure 6-4. At a toll of $0.90, total revenue is given by the sum of the areas A and B. After the toll is raised to $1.10, total revenue is given by the sum of areas B and C. So when the toll is raised, revenue represented by area A is lost but revenue represented by area C is gained.
These two areas have important interpretations. Area C represents the revenue gain that comes from the additional $0.20 paid by drivers who continue to use the bridge. That is, the 900 who continue to use the bridge contribute an additional $0.20 × 900 = $180 per day to total revenue, represented by area C. But 200 drivers who would have used the bridge at a price of $0.90 no longer do so, generating a loss to total revenue of $0.90 × 200 = $180 per day, represented by area A. (In this particular example, because demand is unit-
Except in the rare case of a good with perfectly elastic or perfectly inelastic demand, when a seller raises the price of a good, two countervailing effects are present:
A price effect: After a price increase, each unit sold sells at a higher price, which tends to raise revenue.
A quantity effect: After a price increase, fewer units are sold, which tends to lower revenue.
But then, you may ask, what is the ultimate net effect on total revenue: does it go up or down? The answer is that, in general, the effect on total revenue can go either way—
The price elasticity of demand tells us what happens to total revenue when price changes: its size determines which effect—
If demand for a good is unit-
If demand for a good is inelastic (the price elasticity of demand is less than 1), a higher price increases total revenue. In this case, the price effect is stronger than the quantity effect.
If demand for a good is elastic (the price elasticity of demand is greater than 1), an increase in price reduces total revenue. In this case, the quantity effect is stronger than the price effect.
Table 6-2 shows how the effect of a price increase on total revenue depends on the price elasticity of demand, using the same data as in Figure 6-3. An increase in the price from $0.90 to $1.10 leaves total revenue unchanged at $990 when demand is unit-
The price elasticity of demand also predicts the effect of a fall in price on total revenue. When the price falls, the same two countervailing effects are present, but they work in the opposite directions as compared to the case of a price rise. There is the price effect of a lower price per unit sold, which tends to lower revenue. This is countered by the quantity effect of more units sold, which tends to raise revenue. Which effect dominates depends on the price elasticity. Here is a quick summary:
When demand is unit-
When demand is inelastic, the price effect dominates the quantity effect; so a fall in price reduces total revenue.
When demand is elastic, the quantity effect dominates the price effect; so a fall in price increases total revenue.
Suppose an economist says that “the price elasticity of demand for coffee is 0.25.” What he or she means is that at the current price the elasticity is 0.25. In the previous discussion of the toll bridge, what we were really describing was the elasticity at the price of $0.90. Why this qualification? Because for the vast majority of demand curves, the price elasticity of demand at one point along the curve is different from the price elasticity of demand at other points along the same curve.
To see this, consider the table in Figure 6-5, which shows a hypothetical demand schedule. It also shows in the last column the total revenue generated at each price and quantity combination in the demand schedule. The upper panel of the graph in Figure 6-5 shows the corresponding demand curve. The lower panel illustrates the same data on total revenue: the height of a bar at each quantity demanded—
In Figure 6-5, you can see that when the price is low, raising the price increases total revenue: starting at a price of $1, raising the price to $2 increases total revenue from $9 to $16. This means that when the price is low, demand is inelastic. Moreover, you can see that demand is inelastic on the entire section of the demand curve from a price of $0 to a price of $5.
When the price is high, however, raising it further reduces total revenue: starting at a price of $8, raising the price to $9 reduces total revenue, from $16 to $9. This means that when the price is high, demand is elastic. Furthermore, you can see that demand is elastic over the section of the demand curve from a price of $5 to $10.
For the vast majority of goods, the price elasticity of demand changes along the demand curve. So whenever you measure a good’s elasticity, you are really measuring it at a particular point or section of the good’s demand curve.
During a shortage of flu vaccines, vaccine distributors could significantly raise their prices for two important reasons: substitutes are very difficult to obtain, and the vaccine is seen as a medical necessity.
People are left with a few options. Some will pay high prices to become patients of the expensive private clinics that have access to the vaccine, and some will travel long distances to wait in lines for the chance to get vaccinated. Others will simply do without (and over time may change their habits to avoid catching the flu, such as eating out less often and avoiding mass transit). This illustrates the four main factors that determine elasticity: the availability of close substitutes, whether the good is a necessity or a luxury, the share of income a consumer spends on the good, and how much time has elapsed since the price change. We’ll briefly examine each of these factors.
The Availability of Close Substitutes The price elasticity of demand tends to be high (or elastic) if there are other readily available goods that consumers regard as similar and would be willing to consume instead. The price elasticity of demand tends to be low (or inelastic) if there are no close substitutes or they are very difficult to obtain.
Whether the Good Is a Necessity or a Luxury The price elasticity of demand tends to be low (or inelastic) if a good is something you must have, like a life-saving medicine. The price elasticity of demand tends to be high (or elastic) if the good is a luxury—something you can easily live without.
Share of Income Spent on the Good The price elasticity of demand tends to be low (or inelastic) when spending on a good accounts for a small share of a consumer’s income. In that case, a significant change in the price of the good has little impact on how much the consumer spends. In contrast, when a good accounts for a significant share of a consumer’s spending, the consumer is likely to be very responsive to a change in price. In this case, the price elasticity of demand is high (or elastic).
Time Elapsed Since Price Change In general, the price elasticity of demand tends to increase (or become more elastic) as consumers have more time to adjust to a price change. This means that the long-run price elasticity of demand is often higher (or more elastic) than the short-run elasticity.
A good illustration of the effect of time on the elasticity of demand is drawn from the 1970s, the first time gasoline prices increased dramatically in Canada. Initially, consumption fell very little because there were no close substitutes for gasoline and because driving their cars was necessary for people to carry out the ordinary tasks of life. Over time, however, Canadians changed their habits in ways that enabled them to gradually reduce their gasoline consumption. The result was a steady decline in gasoline consumption over the next decade, even though the price of gasoline did not continue to rise, confirming that the long-run price elasticity of demand for gasoline was indeed much greater than the short-run elasticity. According to a study on the price elasticities of gasoline from 1960 to 1980, the price elasticity of demand for gasoline in Canada in the short run was 0.25, while in the long run it was 1.07.3
It is a well-known fact that airfares between any pair of destinations and the responsiveness of demand to changes in airfares vary significantly. Do they depend on the nature of air travel and the travel distance? Not surprisingly, the answer is yes.
In 2008, the Department of Finance Canada released a summary report on the empirical studies of the price elasticities of demand for air travel in Canada and other major countries. The report found that the price elasticity of air travel varies by the nature of the travel (business or leisure) and the travel distance (short-haul or long-haul). The report summarized the range and median price elasticities of demand for air travel for 6 distinct markets based on 21 Canadian and international studies. The results of the report are summarized in the table.
You probably noticed that the demand for long-haul international flights is more inelastic compared to domestic flights. What causes these differences? Basically, they are driven by the availability of close substitutes. Long-haul international flights are more inelastic for both groups of travellers because of the lack of close substitutes. If you are going abroad, from Toronto to Beijing for example, your travel options are rather limited. With time constraints, travel by air is likely to be the only option; thus, you are less responsive to changes in airfares (prices). The same applies to long-haul domestic flight for both business and leisure travel. The flight may take several hours, but the same trip will take days by car or train. There are better options for short-haul international travel than for long-haul as travellers can reach their destinations by cars, trains, and planes within a reasonable time frame. For example, you can drive from Vancouver to Seattle in roughly the same amount of time as flying.
The report also shows that the demand for air travel for business travel tends to be more inelastic than for leisure travel. For business people, the travel is usually a necessity, so they will be less responsive to a change in airfares. On the other hand, air travel can be a luxury for some vacationers, so they are more responsive to price changes (as they can easily change their vacation destinations). For example, if airfares rise significantly, vacationers have the option to spend their vacation at home or at much closer attractions.
Both these reasons help explain why business people tend to pay more, sometimes a lot more, for what is largely the same service. (Department of Finance Canada, Air Travel Demand Elasticities: Concepts, Issues and Measurement, www.fin.gc.ca/consultresp/Airtravel/airtravStdy_-eng.asp.)
Demand is perfectly inelastic if it is completely unresponsive to price. It is perfectly elastic if it is infinitely responsive to price.
Demand is elastic if the price elasticity of demand is greater than 1. It is inelastic if the price elasticity of demand is less than 1. It is unit-elastic if the price elasticity of demand is exactly 1.
When demand is elastic, the quantity effect of a price increase dominates the price effect and total revenue falls. When demand is inelastic, the price effect of a price increase dominates the quantity effect and total revenue rises.
Because the price elasticity of demand can change along the demand curve, economists refer to a particular point on the demand curve when speaking of “the” price elasticity of demand.
Ready availability of close substitutes makes demand for a good more elastic, as does the length of time elapsed since the price change. Demand for a necessity is less elastic, and demand for a luxury good is more elastic. Demand tends to be inelastic for goods that absorb a small share of a consumer’s income and elastic for goods that absorb a large share of income.
CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING 6-2
For each case, choose the condition that characterizes demand: elastic demand, inelastic demand, or unit-elastic demand.
Total revenue decreases when price increases.
The additional revenue generated by an increase in quantity sold is exactly offset by revenue lost from the fall in price received per unit.
Total revenue falls when output increases.
Producers in an industry find they can increase their total revenues by coordinating a reduction in industry output.
Elastic demand. Consumers are highly responsive to changes in price. For a rise in price, the quantity effect (which tends to reduce total revenue) outweighs the price effect (which tends to increase total revenue). Overall, this leads to a fall in total revenue.
Unit-elastic demand. Here the revenue lost to the fall in price is exactly equal to the revenue gained from higher sales. The quantity effect exactly offsets the price effect.
Inelastic demand. Consumers are relatively unresponsive to changes in price. For consumers to purchase a given percentage increase in output, the price must fall by an even greater percentage. The price effect of a fall in price (which tends to reduce total revenue) outweighs the quantity effect (which tends to increase total revenue). As a result, total revenue decreases.
Inelastic demand. Consumers are relatively unresponsive to price, so a given percentage fall in output is accompanied by an even greater percentage rise in price. The price effect of a rise in price (which tends to increase total revenue) outweighs the quantity effect (which tends to reduce total revenue). As a result, total revenue increases.
For the following goods, what is the elasticity of demand? Explain. What is the shape of the demand curve?
Demand for a blood transfusion by an accident victim
Demand by students for green erasers
The demand of an accident victim for a blood transfusion is very likely to be perfectly inelastic because there is no substitute and it is necessary for survival. The demand curve will be vertical, at a quantity equal to the needed transfusion quantity.
Students’ demand for green erasers is likely to be perfectly elastic because there are easily available substitutes: nongreen erasers. The demand curve will be horizontal, at a price equal to that of non-green erasers.