It’s not difficult to see why banking crises normally lead to recessions. There are three main reasons: a credit crunch arising from reduced availability of credit, financial distress caused by a debt overhang, and the loss of monetary policy effectiveness.
In a credit crunch, potential borrowers either can’t get credit at all or must pay very high interest rates.
A debt overhang occurs when a vicious circle of deleveraging leaves a borrower with high debt but diminished assets.
Recall how the Fed normally responds to a recession: it engages in open-market operations, purchasing short-term government debt from banks. This leaves banks with excess reserves, which they lend out, leading to a fall in interest rates and causing an economic expansion through increased consumer and investment spending.
Under normal conditions, this policy response is highly effective. In the aftermath of a banking crisis, though, the whole process tends to break down. Banks, fearing runs by depositors or a loss of confidence by their creditors, tend to hold on to excess reserves rather than lend them out. Meanwhile, businesses and consumers, finding themselves in financial difficulty due to the plunge in asset prices, may be unwilling to borrow even if interest rates fall. As a result, even very low interest rates may not be enough to push the economy back to full employment.
The economy is in a liquidity trap when conventional monetary policy is ineffective because nominal interest rates are up against the zero bound.
In Chapter 17 we discussed the fact that interest rates can’t go below zero—called the zero bound for interest rates. A situation in which conventional monetary policy, such as cutting interest rates, can’t be used to fight a slump because nominal interest rates are up against the zero bound is known as a liquidity trap. In fact, all the historical episodes in which the zero bound for interest rates became an important constraint on policy—the 1930s, Japan in the 1990s, and a number of countries after 2008—have occurred after a major banking crisis.
555
The inability of the usual tools of monetary policy to offset the macroeconomic devastation caused by banking crises is the major reason such crises produce deep, prolonged slumps. The obvious solution is to look for other policy tools. In fact, governments do typically take a variety of special steps when banks are in crisis.