Chapter Summary

Chapter Summary

Section 1: Externalities

Taking care of the front lawn creates an external benefit to the neighbors.
Jose Luis Pelaez Inc/Getty Images

Externalities, or spillovers, arise when a transaction benefits or harms parties not involved in the transaction.

Factories spewing dirty smoke create an external cost to the area residents.
Oote Boe 3/Alamy

Externalities lead to market failure when external benefits or external costs push markets away from the socially optimal output.

Bob Krist/Corbis

The Coase theorem suggests that when transactions costs are near zero, bargaining between parties will lead to an efficient allocation of resources no matter how property rights are allocated.

Example: If students have the right to party, the neighbors can pay the students to stay quiet. If neighbors have the right to a quiet environment, students can pay the neighbors for the right to party. Either way, those with the property rights can exercise their rights or accept payment to forgo the rights.

Section 2: Public Goods

Accent Alaska.com/Alamy




Public goods exhibit two characteristics:

Nonrivalry: One person’s consumption of a good does not reduce the availability of that good to others.

Nonexcludability: Once a good has been provided, no consumers can be excluded from consuming the product. Public goods lead to market failure when individuals lack the incentive to pay for them, leading to such goods being underprovided.

Common property resources are owned by the community, and therefore individuals tend to overuse and overexploit them.

360

Section 3: Environmental Policy

A surprising source of pollution is the methane and ammonia gases produced by cows through belching and flatulence, contributing approximately 14% of the world’s greenhouse gases.
Kevin Britland/Alamy

Environmental policies depend on the discount rate chosen for how society values events in the future. A high discount rate places a significant burden on future generations, while a low discount rate places a greater burden on the current generation.

The optimal pollution level in a society is rarely zero. Instead, some pollution is acceptable if the cost of abatement exceeds its benefit. Therefore, optimal pollution levels are found where marginal abatement costs (MAC) equal the marginal damage caused by pollution. As long as the cleanup costs exceed damage, it would be optimal to allow pollution until MAC equals MD at ES.

Environmental policy aimed at addressing market failure takes on several forms:

  • Command and control: fixed standards for polluters that are enforced through inspections and legal action (does not always lead to optimal pollution levels).
  • Effluent taxes: a fee that is paid to the government per unit of pollution emitted (can lead to optimal pollution levels if the fee is set appropriately).
  • Pollution permits: also known as cap-and-trade, allows firms to buy, sell, and trade permits to pollute (can lead to optimal pollution levels).

Section 4: Putting It All Together: An Analysis of Climate Change

Crowded streets filled with polluting vehicles are a common scene in India, contributing to global pollution as the nation develops.
Randy Olson/National Olson/National



Global climate change is a huge global negative externality accompanied by public goods aspects and extremely long time horizons, making the inherent market failure difficult to address.

Equity issues arise when some countries (often developed) pay significantly more to reduce global climate change than developing countries.

Solutions to global pollution require cooperation between nations and global carbon pricing that is credible and covers the full costs of carbon-based products.

361