13.4 13.3 Fair Division and Organ Transplant Policies

In 1984, the U.S. Congress passed the National Organ Transplant Act and established a unified transplant network known as the Organ Procurement and Transplantation Network (OPTN). One of the primary goals of the OPTN was to increase the equity in the national system of organ allocation.

Achieving an equitable system of organ allocation is complicated by factors other than demand exceeding supply. For example, should an available organ go to the patient who needs it the most or to the one for whom the likelihood of a successful transplant is greatest? Should both of these be taken into consideration, and if so, how? Questions such as these reveal the extent to which an equitable system of organ allocation is a challenging problem in fair division.

547

To illustrate some of the issues (and paradoxes!) arising in the search for an equitable system for organ allocation, we’ll (roughly) follow Peyton Young’s synopsis of the fair division procedure for kidney allocation adopted by the OPTN in the late 1980s (see Suggested Readings on page 570).

There were three (main) criteria used in arriving at a final ranking of those needing a kidney, and each potential recipient was awarded points according to a fixed method that we now describe.

To illustrate this allocation procedure, let’s assume we have five potential recipients—, , , , and —with the following characteristics:

Potential
Recipient
Months
Waiting
Antigens
Matched
Percent
Sensitized
5 2 10
4.5 2 20
4 0 0
2 3 60
1 6 90

According to the procedure we described, points would be allocated as follows:

Potential
Recipient
Months
Waiting
Antigens
Matched
Percent
Sensitized
Total
Points
10 4 1 15
8 4 2 14
6 0 0 6
4 6 6 16
2 12 9 23

548

Thus, if one kidney became available, it would go to (with 23 points). Presumably, if two kidneys became available at the same time, would get one and (with 16 points) would get the other.

But now things get interesting. Peyton Young, being well versed in the paradoxes of voting theory, fair division, and apportionment (among other things), observed the following possibility: What if two kidneys become available, but one is delayed slightly? Presumably, gets the first one, and then we redo the chart with only , , , and . This yields the following:

Potential
Recipient
Months
Waiting
Antigens
Matched
Percent
Sensitized
5 2 10
4.5 2 20
4 0 0
2 3 60

According to the procedure that we described, points would be allocated as follows:

Potential
Recipient
Months
Waiting
Antigens
Matched
Percent
Sensitized
Total
Points
10 4 1 15
7.5 4 2 13.5
5 0 0 5
2.5 6 6 14.5

Thus, (not ) now gets the second kidney, having 15 points to 14.5 for . This is an example of what is called the “priority paradox.” For more on this, consult Peyton Young’s book, listed in the Suggested Readings.