lemons problem
An asymmetric information problem that occurs when a seller knows more about the quality of the good he is selling than does the buyer.
A common manifestation of asymmetric information in markets is the lemons problem. This problem exists when the sellers know more about the quality of a good they are selling than the buyer does. The used car example in the introduction is one such case. It is, in fact, the origin of the problem’s name, because poor-
To see how damaging the lemons problem can be to markets, consider the following example. (It is overly simplistic but makes clear what the effect is, the way it works, and why it can cause such problems.) Suppose there are two types of used cars: good ones (we’ll call them “plums”) and bad ones (“lemons”). Half of used cars are plums, and the other half are lemons. Potential buyers value plums at $10,000, but lemons have no value to them. Sellers value plums at $8,000 and also have no value for lemons.
Let’s start by thinking about this market if the quality of cars were observable to both the sellers (the current owners of the cars) and the buyers. Because sellers value plums at less than buyers do ($8,000 vs. $10,000), the half of used cars that are of good quality will sell at prices between $8,000 and $10,000. (Any price in this range will work.) Both parties are better off because of the trade: Buyers value the cars more than their former owners did, and the cars are sold at a price that makes both the buyer and seller no worse off than had no trade occurred (in fact, at least one of them must be better off). Lemons have no value to either their current owners or potential buyers, so no lemons will be sold, and no one is better or worse off as a result of this outcome.
Thus, when quality is fully observable to everyone, buyers and sellers in the market are at least as well off—
Now consider what happens under asymmetric information, when sellers know if their cars are plums or lemons, but buyers do not. (It’s reasonable that car owners would know more about the quality of their own cars because they’ve experienced all of the cars’ problems.) All that buyers know is that half of used cars available for sale are plums and half are lemons. They realize that the probability that any particular car is a plum is 50%.
What is the most that a buyer will pay for a used car? Because she values a plum at $10,000 and a lemon at $0, and a car has a 50% chance of being either, the most a buyer would be willing to pay for a used car is ($10,000 × 0.50) + ($0 × 0.50) = $5,000. Anything more than that and she will be worse off in expectation: Any one car only has an expected value of $5,000.
617
But now, think about the owner of a plum deciding whether to sell it. This seller values his car at $8,000. Because buyers can’t know for sure whether or not his car is a plum, he could never get more than $5,000 by selling it. As a result, the seller won’t sell a plum car, only a lemon. But, here’s the problem: Buyers are not stupid. They recognize that the owners of good cars won’t sell when the price is $5,000, so buyers know that any used car available for sale must be a lemon. Because buyers don’t want lemons for $5,000, they are not willing to buy any used car that is actually offered for sale.
This is the tragedy of the lemons problem. We have a situation in which we know that if information were equally known by both buyers and sellers, there would be a large set of used car sales that would make people better off (because buyers value the plum cars more than their former owners did). With enough asymmetric information, however, no sales take place. There is no market. All those potential gains from exchange are destroyed because one side knows more than the other.
This example brings up two important points about asymmetric information and the lemons problem. The first is that the existence of quality differences is not, by itself, the cause of the difficulty. If there were complete information in the market and the quality of products were common knowledge, higher-
The lemons problem arises when information about quality is not known equally by the buyer and seller. This asymmetry leads to poor-
adverse selection
A situation in which market characteristics lead to more low-
When there are stronger incentives for “bad” types of a product to be involved in a transaction than “good” types of the product, we call that adverse selection (so named because the selection of types into the market tilts adversely toward those of bad quality). In our used car case, lemons are the “bad” types. They are disproportionately likely to be put up for sale because buyers can’t tell the difference between lemons and good cars. This makes the price buyers are willing to pay for a used car of uncertain quality too low to induce owners of good cars to sell. The sellers who are willing to offer their cars for sale at this price must therefore be lemon owners. (Adverse selection on the buy side of the market can also cause problems. We’ll see that below in our discussion of the insurance market.)
The second important point in this example is that information asymmetry harms not only those with less information, but also those who have more information. Both sides lose because information asymmetries keep sales from taking place that would have benefited both buyers and sellers. In our example, buyers and owners of good used cars suffer because they miss out on trades that would happen if each side knew the car’s quality. Paradoxically, rather than their information edge being an advantage for the sellers, it is a hindrance.
Could sellers get around this problem by telling potential buyers that their car is indeed a plum? The problem is that lemon sellers have an incentive to lie about the quality of their cars and try to pass them off as plums. If buyers recognize this incentive to lie, then a seller saying the car is a plum won’t be informative about its true quality. Without additional information, a buyer won’t be able to tell a plum seller (claiming a high-
618
The specific example we ran through above was, as we said, purposely simplistic. Lemons problems usually don’t completely destroy markets. After all, we see plenty of cars purchased in the used car market in the real world. However, adverse selection can still reduce trade to a level below what is economically efficient. The vicious cycle of uncertain quality still reduces buyers’ willingness to pay, leading in turn to low-
For example, in reality there is a much broader distribution of quality among used cars than the two-
Adverse selection is why, when considering buying a used car, you are likely to have the type of concerns about quality discussed in the introduction to this chapter. You recognize, for example, that the late-
Potential lemons problems abound in the economy. We’ve discussed the most well-
Adverse selection is common in services and factor (input) markets, too. People seeking to remodel their homes confront the lemons problem, for example. It is difficult to judge the quality of workmanship to expect from a contractor. This concern might make homeowners reluctant to offer adequate compensation to contractors who bid on a job. But, this reluctance would, in turn, reduce the likelihood of a high-
In input markets, lemons problems can show up in used capital goods sales. Trucks, machine tools, and even buildings are often bought from sellers who know more about their quality than buyers. Labor markets can have their own adverse selection issues. Suppose workers differ in, and know, their “quality”—which could be their willingness to work hard, their honesty, or their knowledge of the tasks necessary for the job. If a firm could readily observe the quality type of any worker, it could pay him his marginal product (which will be higher for higher-
619
Because lemons problems can destroy so much economic value by keeping beneficial exchanges from happening, many institutions in real-
Institutions and market mechanisms that address asymmetric information in the used car market basically work in one of three ways. One set acts to solve the asymmetric information problem directly, by giving buyers the ability to observe a car’s quality before any transaction. The second set of institutions works by punishing sellers who try to sell cars they know are lemons but still pass them off as higher quality. The third set reduces adverse selection by increasing the number of high-
Reducing Asymmetric Information Directly There are several ways potential buyers can learn about the quality of a used car. Buyers can have a trusted mechanic who is not affiliated with the seller check out the car before agreeing to purchase it, for example. Owners can make their cars’ ownership and maintenance records available. (Remember our earlier discussion about why sellers may take the initiative to close the information gap, even though they know more about quality than buyers. Both parties lose—
Some companies have made a successful business model out of reducing information asymmetries. Autocheck and Carfax specialize in providing information about used cars. Customers can type a car’s unique Vehicle Information Number into either company’s Web site and immediately see the ownership history of the car, and sometimes the maintenance records, too. This is valuable information for buyers, but sellers also benefit from the service. In fact, a large fraction of Autocheck and Carfax searches are paid for not by buyers, but instead by auto dealers who have bought subscriptions that allow their customers to do background searches on cars the buyers are considering.
Incentives for Truthful Quality Reporting The second set of institutions reduces the lemons problem by making it costly for sellers to be dishonest about their cars’ quality. These mechanisms can work even if they don’t actually give the buyer all the information about the car that the seller knows.
A classic example of this type of mechanism is reputation, a potential buyer’s perception of a seller. Businesses that operate honestly (by selling good-
Reputation incentives work best when a business expects to operate for a long time, because a good reputation pays off in increased business in the future. A “fly-
Warranties can also reduce adverse selection. High-
620
Well-
Increasing the Average Quality of Cars Placed on the Market The lemons problem can be lessened if something reduces adverse selection. Bringing more plums onto the market, even if the quality of individual cars is still unobservable, would achieve this. Raising the average quality of cars available increases buyers’ willingness to pay for used cars. This increase in demand further encourages owners of higher-
Leasing programs are one way to make this happen. With a lease, a buyer or “lessee” takes ownership of a car for a set period of time, with the option to return the car to the seller (the “lessor”) at the end of the contract period. By encouraging the return of vehicles at a predetermined date regardless of their quality, leasing increases the number of higher-
Beyond Used Cars These examples show that the lemons problem, while potentially very damaging to markets, also offers powerful incentives for people and firms to take actions that limit its reach. The examples discussed all involve the used car market, but it is easy to find similarly structured mechanisms working in other markets with asymmetric information.
For instance, we see similar institutions at work in our home repair services and labor market examples discussed earlier. In home repair, referral networks enable homeowners to learn more about contractors’ performance and specialties before they hire them. Angie’s List is a company that compiles grades on contractors from their previous clients. Homeowners can use these grades when considering which contractor to hire. (Such information is valuable. Over a million people have purchased memberships allowing them to view these grades.) Angie’s List and other business rating organizations like the Better Business Bureau also enhance the benefits to contractors of preserving a good reputation.
Referrals and reputations play a key role in labor markets, too. You normally list references on your résumé. Firms often check with these references and previous employers about a potential employee’s performance. Other institutions—
621
These examples are good news. Even though the lemons problem can potentially destroy markets, it has spurred the creation of institutions that moderate its impact. In some cases, these institutions are so effective that they remove the effects of information asymmetries on trading. Nevertheless, it’s important to remember that even then, the lemons problem still influences those markets. Buyers remain concerned about the quality of the used car they buy. It’s just that the buyers are better able to obtain a good sense of the car’s quality before purchase and pay the appropriate price for it.
For interactive, step-
Suppose that consumers value a high-
Assume that buyers believe there is a 50% probability that a used laptop will be of high quality. What would be the price that buyers are willing to pay for any used laptop?
If the price determined in (a) is offered in the market for used laptops, how many high-
What would you expect to happen over time as information about the true odds of buying a high-
Solution:
If buyers expect that 50% of the used laptops available are of high quality (meaning that the other 50% are of low quality), then the expected value of a laptop is equal to
0.50 × $400 + 0.50 × $100 = $200 + $50 = $250
Therefore, $250 would be the most that buyers are willing to pay for a used laptop.
If the price of a used laptop is $250, then the quantity supplied of high-
Therefore, there will be 600 used laptops for sale (150 of high quality and 450 of low quality). The probability of buying a used laptop of high quality is not 50%, but actually equal to 150/600 = 0.25 or 25%. Because of asymmetric information, buyers are not willing to pay a very high price for a used laptop. Therefore, the owners of high-
Over time, buyers will adjust their expected value of used laptops. This will further reduce the price buyers are willing to pay. Owners of high-
622
Collectibles like coins, stamps, and antiques have inherent lemons problems. The subtlest of differences, at least as perceived by experts, can cause otherwise similar items to vary greatly in quality and resale value. Expert dealers can use their superior knowledge about what affects the quality of such goods to take advantage of less knowledgeable buyers. Some recent research has looked closely at how reputation mechanisms reduce this sort of asymmetric information problem in collectibles markets.
Luís Cabral and Ali Hortaçsu investigated a key reputation mechanism on eBay: feedback scores.5 Buyers and sellers on eBay can comment on and rate their interactions. Ratings histories allow eBay users to build reputations for fair dealing by engaging in a number of transactions where the other party is satisfied (and willing to state this). Dishonest actions like misrepresenting a product’s quality can be reported to discourage others from dealing with the scofflaw.
Cabral and Hortaçsu looked specifically at the impact of sellers’ ratings in a sample of collectibles markets. They measured how changes in sellers’ ratings impact future sales and find stark effects consistent with large reputation costs. For example, there is a “steep first step” when a seller loses what was up to that point a spotless rating history. Sellers averaged sales growth rates of 7% in the week prior to their first negative rating, but their sales fell 7% the week after. Additional negative ratings had smaller impacts on sales, but this isn’t much of a consolation to sellers: Negative ratings are also more frequent after a seller’s first.
Losing one’s reputation is also correlated with leaving the market: Seller exits are often preceded by a burst of negative ratings. The direction of cause-
In a different study, John List showed that reputation’s ability to shrink the lemons problem is more powerful when it is paired with verification from third-
The items that List’s subjects offered to buy were not quality-
After the purchases were made, List had the offered items professionally graded to determine their true quality level. If reputation were important to dealers, they would likely respond to higher dollar offers by giving the purchaser a higher-
623
List’s results showed an interesting split. Dealers who reported (on a survey taken after the experiment was finished) that they were locally based or otherwise frequented the particular show where the experiment was conducted did, in fact, give higher-
The importance of third-
Verification and reputation therefore work hand-
In lemons-
In insurance markets, buyers may know more about their risk of needing to make claims on their insurance policies. Think about what insurance is: a good that compensates a policyholder when particular events occur. Depending on the type of insurance, these events could involve the policyholder getting sick, being in a car accident, having a tree fall on his house, or even death. Individuals expecting such events to be more likely will obviously assign a greater value to being insured. If you know you need expensive braces for your teeth, for example, you would greatly value dental insurance because it would help pay for your orthodontia.
But this means that buyers are adversely selected in insurance markets. From the standpoint of insurance companies, potential customers differ in “quality” because they have different likelihoods of making claims on their policies. (The expected sizes of their claims can be different, too.) Risky drivers are more likely to make claims on their auto insurance policies; unhealthy individuals are more likely to make health insurance claims.
Just as with the “seller-
624
The adverse selection problem occurs when the customer knows more about their expected claim behavior than insurers do. Insurance companies realize that the riskiest customers will be those most likely to buy insurance, and will buy more insurance than low-
This starts the vicious cycle again: The high premiums price some low-
Adverse selection on the buyer side of a market can therefore be as damaging as adverse selection on the seller side. And just as in the cases above, the party with more information can be hurt just as much as the party with less information. In particular, low-
Just as we saw in the markets with seller-
Group Policies One example is the writing of group insurance policies. These are general policies written for members of a specified group, often defined as employees of particular firms. In the United States, most people get their health insurance this way, for example. Why does group insurance help with adverse selection? By tying insurance to employment status, the insurance company removes much of the link between individuals’ riskiness and their insurance purchases. That is, it pools together a wider range of risk types. The good risks are added to the bad, reducing the correlation between individuals seeking to buy health insurance and their chances of falling ill. This is in many ways similar to the way in which leasing reduces the lemons problem in the used car market by breaking the tie between a car’s quality and its likelihood of being resold. (It also doesn’t hurt, from the insurance company’s perspective, that unhealthy people are less likely to be employed. This, too, reduces adverse selection.)
Screening A second adverse selection reduction tactic is screening. Insurance companies vet potential customers for the likelihood of their submitting claims by observing as many risk factors as possible. People seeking life insurance, for example, typically have to complete a medical questionnaire and submit to blood and urine tests, and sometimes a full medical exam. Having a risk factor present doesn’t necessarily mean that a potential policyholder will be denied coverage. Once his risk is known by both the buyer and seller, the customer might still be offered coverage, but he would have to pay higher premiums that match his riskiness. For example, life insurance premiums are higher for smokers, diabetics, or those with high blood pressure. Screening for risk factors isn’t constrained to direct influences on expected claims. If you have purchased auto insurance, in addition to asking questions about your driving habits and running a records check for moving violations and accidents, the insurer may have asked you to supply an academic transcript to take advantage of a good-
626
Online Ratings and Information Asymmetries
625
The definition of the word “yelp” is “a short, sharp cry, especially of pain or alarm.” And yelp is exactly what Tracy Chan, a dentist in San Francisco, did the day after receiving a call from Yelp, the Web site and app that publishes crowd-
Chan filed a lawsuit against Yelp claiming that the company had intentionally manipulated her reviews so that she either had to pay for advertising or watch her business sink as bad review upon bad review piled up. Three other business owners also made similar allegations in supporting affidavits, asserting that Yelp was not just manipulating existing reviews to force businesses to buy advertising but also fabricating new reviews and posting them under fake names. The judge dismissed this particular case on the grounds of insufficient factual evidence, but it wasn’t the only time the integrity of Yelp’s reviews has been called into question. Yelp has been involved in a number of lawsuits, and, in one notable case in 2013, the judge deemed Yelp’s approach, “the modern-
*Tom Gara, “Another Day in Court for Yelp,” Wall Street Journal, May 21, 2013. http:/
Why have Yelp’s practices fueled such an uproar? If everyone already knew how good or bad each business was, Yelp’s reviews wouldn’t matter. But, especially in big cities, potential customers can’t possibly know the quality of every restaurant, spa, and dentist’s office. Information asymmetries exist. As a result, a profile on Yelp with a lot of five-
One impact of online reviews is to produce better customer service. When the cost for customers of acquiring information on quality falls, firms have an incentive to serve clients better. But better customer service is hard work . . . maybe there is an easier way to attract customers. That is what economists Dina Mayzlin, Yaniv Dover, and Judith Chevalier set out to explore by looking at data on online hotel reviews.†
†Dina Mayzlin, Yaniv Dover, and Judith Chevalier, “Promotional Reviews: An Empirical Investigation of Online Review Manipulation,” American Economic Review 104, no. 8 (August 2014): 2421–
The authors looked at hotel reviews posted on both TripAdvisor, where anyone can post a review, and Expedia.com, where only those who have booked at least one night at the hotel in the last six months can post a review. Because its posts are not restricted to known customers, it is easier to post a fake review on TripAdvisor. Can you guess who posts fake reviews? The hotels themselves! And not only positive reviews for their own hotel, but negative reviews for competing hotels. The authors found that hotels with close neighbors see an increase of 1.9 percentage points in the share of negative reviews on TripAdvisor as compared to Expedia.com. The worst offenders are independent hotels run by the owner. If your hotel is located next to one of these, you can expect an average of six more negative reviews on your TripAdvisor page, but no difference on Expedia.
Are Web sites and apps like Yelp and TripAdvisor happy to see all of these fake reviews streaming in? Well, because Yelp may be writing some of the reviews itself, they’re certainly not always bad for business—
Denying Coverage Insurers can also try to head off adverse selection directly by outright denying coverage to individuals with certain risk factors. Health insurance policies often will not cover conditions that already existed at the time the policy was purchased. If you could buy insurance after you became ill, many people would not buy it beforehand. Insurers would pay out massive claims while receiving little premium revenues. If this happened often enough, no one—
This problem explains the economics behind the “mandate” rules in the Affordable Care Act (aka Obamacare) and the Massachusetts health care insurance law on which it was patterned. Both policies have provisions that forbid health insurers from denying anyone coverage, but also mandate that everyone must buy health insurance. While controversial, the mandates help solve what could otherwise be extreme adverse selection problems. The mandate is a lot like a government-
Summing Up These mechanisms and others like them moderate adverse selection in insurance markets for the same reasons that the seller-
Buyer-
Economists Sumit Agarwal, Souphala Chomsisengphet, and Chunlin Liu tested this idea using a series of experiments in the credit card market.7 The experiment had a large financial institution use direct mail to offer new credit cards to potential customers. The offers varied randomly in their financial terms, some more favorable than others. Agarwal, Chomsisengphet, and Liu found that customers who sent back an application for a card were significantly worse credit risks than those who received a mailing but did not send an application. This suggests that adverse selection was occurring in the market, even though the set of borrowers targeted for the solicitations were considered to be part of a low-
627
Agarwal, Chomsisengphet, and Liu then followed the credit histories of those borrowers for whom the bank approved cards. Even though approval meant the cardholders had to pass the bank’s credit screening process, they found that those who applied for and received the cards with the worst terms were the most likely to miss their payments once they started using the cards.
Therefore, even among a pool of customers considered “good” credit risks, adverse selection exists in the credit card market. Raising cards’ rates to try to recoup the losses from a riskier set of cardholders only serves to make the problem worse. The existence of this issue in the market implies that there are potential borrowers out there who can’t find credit because they aren’t able to distinguish themselves from more risky borrowers in the eyes of card issuers.