5.1 How Income Changes Affect an Individual’s Consumption Choices

income effect

The change in a consumer’s consumption choices that results from a change in the purchasing power of the consumer’s income.

In Section 4.3, we learned how changes in income affect the position of a consumer’s budget constraint. Lower incomes shift the constraint toward the origin; higher incomes shift it out. In this section, we look at how a change in income affects a consumer’s utility-maximizing consumption decisions. This is known as the income effect. To isolate this effect, we hold everything else constant during our analysis. Specifically, we assume that the consumer’s preferences (reflected in the utility function and its associated indifference curves) and the prices of the goods stay the same.

Figure 5.1 shows the effect of an increase in income on consumption for Evan, a consumer who allocates his income between vacations and tickets to basketball games. Initially, Evan’s budget constraint is BC1 and the utility-maximizing consumption bundle occurs at point A, where indifference curve U1 is tangent to BC1. If the prices of vacations and basketball tickets remain unchanged, an increase in Evan’s income means that he can afford more of both goods. As a result, the increase in income induces a parallel, outward shift in the budget constraint from BC1 to BC2. Note that, because we hold prices fixed, the slope of the budget constraint (the ratio of the goods’ prices) remains fixed. The new optimal consumption bundle at this higher income level is B, the point where indifference curve U2 is tangent to BC2.

image
Figure 5.1: Figure 5.1 Consumer’s Response to an Increase in Income When Both Goods Are Normal
Figure 5.1: Evan allocates his income between two normal goods, vacations and tickets to basketball games. His initial budget constraint BC1 is tangent to the utility curve U1 at the optimal consumption bundle A. An increase in Evan’s income is represented by the outward parallel shift of BC1 to BC2. Because the prices of the goods are unchanged, Evan can now afford to buy more vacations and basketball tickets, and his new utility-maximizing bundle is B, where utility curve U2 is tangent to BC2. At bundle B, Evan’s consumption of vacations and basketball tickets rises from Qv to Qv and Qb to Qb, respectively.

Because U2 shows bundles of goods that offer a higher utility level than those on U1, the increase in income allows Evan to achieve a higher utility level. Note that when we analyze the effect of changes in income on consumer behavior, we hold preferences (as well as prices) constant. Thus, indifference curve U2 does not appear because of some income-driven shift in preferences. U2 was always there even when Evan’s income was lower. At the lower income, however, point B and all other bundles on U2 (and any other higher indifference curves) were infeasible because Evan could not afford them.

157

Normal and Inferior Goods

normal good

A good for which consumption rises when income rises.

Notice how the new optimum in Figure 5.1 involves higher levels of consumption for both goods. The number of vacations Evan takes rises from Qv to Qv′, and the number of basketball tickets increases from Qb to Qb′. This result isn’t that surprising; Evan was spending money on both vacations and basketball tickets before his income went up, so we might expect that he’d spend some of his extra income on both goods. Economists call a good for which consumption rises when income rises—that is, a good for which the income effect is positive—a normal good. Vacations and basketball tickets are normal goods for Evan. As “normal” suggests, most goods have positive income effects.

inferior good

A good for which consumption decreases when income rises.

It is possible that an increase in income can lead to a consumer consuming a smaller quantity of a good. Recall from Chapter 2 that economists call such goods inferior goods. Figure 5.2 presents an example in which one of the goods is inferior. An increase in the consumer’s income from BC1 to BC2 leads to more steak being consumed, but less macaroni and cheese. Note that it isn’t just that the quantity of mac and cheese relative to the quantity of steak falls. This change can happen even when both goods are normal (i.e., they both rise, but steak rises more). Instead, it is the absolute quantity of macaroni and cheese consumed that drops in the move from A to B, because Qm is less than Qm. Note also that this drop is optimal from the consumer’s perspective—B is her utility-maximizing bundle given her budget constraint BC2, and this bundle offers a higher utility level than A because indifference curve U2 represents a higher utility level than U1.

image
Figure 5.2: Figure 5.2 Consumer’s Response to an Increase in Income When One Good Is Inferior
Figure 5.2: When a good is inferior, an increase in a consumer’s income decreases the consumer’s consumption of that good. Here, mac and cheese is an inferior good, while steak is a normal good. When the consumer’s income increases, shifting the budget constraint outward from BC1 to BC2, she consumes less mac and cheese and more steak at the optimal consumption bundle. From initial optimal consumption bundle A to her new optimal consumption bundle B, the quantity of mac and cheese consumed decreases from Qm to Qm while her consumption of the normal good steak increases from Qs to Qs.

What kind of goods tend to be inferior? Usually, they are goods that are perceived to be low-quality or otherwise undesirable. Examples might include generic cereal brands, secondhand clothing, nights spent in youth hostels, and Spam. When we say Spam, we mean the kind you buy in the grocery store, not the kind you get via e-mail. Junk e-mail probably isn’t a good at all, but rather a “bad.”

158

We do know that every good can’t be inferior, however. If a consumer were to consume a smaller quantity of everything when his income rises, he wouldn’t be spending all his new, higher income. This outcome would be inconsistent with utility maximization, which states that a consumer always ends up buying a bundle on his budget constraint. (Remember there is no saving in this model.)

Whether the effect of an income change on a good’s consumption is positive (consumption increases) or negative (consumption decreases) can vary with the level of income. (We look at some of these special cases later in the chapter.) For instance, a good such as a used car is likely to be a normal good at low levels of income, and an inferior good at high levels of income. When someone’s income is very low, owning a used car is prohibitively expensive and riding a bike or taking public transportation is necessary. As income increases from such low levels, a used car becomes increasingly likely to be purchased, making it a normal good. But once someone becomes rich enough, used cars are supplanted by new cars and his consumption of used cars falls. Over that higher income range, the used car is an inferior good.

Income Elasticities and Types of Goods

income elasticity

The percentage change in the quantity consumed of a good in response to a 1% change in income.

We’ve discussed how the income effect can be positive (as with normal goods) or negative (as with inferior goods). We can make further distinctions between types of goods by looking not just at the sign of the income effect, but at the income elasticity as well, which we discussed in Chapter 2. Remember that the income elasticity measures the percentage change in the quantity consumed of a good in response to a given percentage change in income. Formally, the income elasticity is

image

where Q is the quantity of the good consumed (ΔQ is the change in quantity), and I is income (ΔI is the change in income). As we noted in our earlier discussion, income elasticity is like the price elasticity of demand, except that we are now considering the responsiveness of consumption to income changes rather than to price changes.

The first ratio in the income elasticity definition is the income effect shown in the equations above: ΔQI, the change in quantity consumed in response to a change in income. Therefore, the sign of the income elasticity is the same as the sign of the income effect. For normal goods, ΔQI > 0, and the income elasticity is positive. For inferior goods, ΔQI < 0, and the income elasticity is negative.

necessity good

normal good for which income elasticity is between zero and 1.

Within the class of normal goods, economists occasionally make a further distinction. The quantities of goods with an income elasticity between zero and 1 (sometimes called necessity goods) rise with income, but at a slower rate. Because prices are held constant when measuring income elasticities, the slower-than-income quantity growth implies the share of a consumer’s budget devoted to the good falls as income grows. Many normal goods fit into this category, especially items that just about everyone uses or needs, like toothpaste, salt, socks, and electricity. Someone who earns $1 million a year may well consume more of these goods (or more expensive varieties) than an aspiring artist who earns $10,000 annually, but the millionaire, whose income is 100 times greater than the artist’s, is unlikely to spend 100 times more on toothpaste (or salt, or socks . . .) than the artist spends.

luxury good

A good with an income elasticity greater than 1.

Luxury goods have an income elasticity greater than 1. Because their quantities consumed grow faster than income does, these goods account for an increasing fraction of the consumer’s expenditure as income rises. First-class airline tickets, jewelry, and beach homes are all likely to be luxury goods.

159

The Income Expansion Path

Imagine repeating the analysis in the previous section for every possible income level, starting with 0. That is, for a given set of prices and a particular set of preferences, find the utility-maximizing bundle for every possible budget constraint, where each constraint corresponds to a different income level. Those optimal bundles will be located wherever an indifference curve is tangent to a budget line. In the examples above, bundles A and B were optimal at the two income levels.

Figure 5.3 shows how Meredith allocates her income between bus rides and bottled water. Points A, B, C, D, and E are the optimal consumption bundles at five different income levels that correspond to the budget constraints shown. Point A is Meredith’s utility-maximizing bundle for the lowest of the five income levels, point B is the bundle for the second-lowest income, and so on. Note that the indifference curves themselves come from Meredith’s utility function. We have chosen various shapes here just to illustrate that these points can move around in different ways.

image
Figure 5.4: Figure 5.3 Income Expansion Path
Figure 5.4: Meredith’s income expansion path connects all of the optimal bundles of bottled water and bus rides for each income level. Points A, B, C, D, and E are optimal consumption bundles associated with budget constraints BC1 through BC5. Where both bottled water and bus rides are normal goods, the income expansion path is upward-sloping. At incomes higher than that shown at the budget constraint BC4 and to the right of bundle D, bus rides become inferior goods, and the income expansion path slopes downward.

income expansion path

A curve that connects a consumer’s optimal bundles at each income level.

If we draw a line connecting all the optimal bundles (the five here plus all the others for budget constraints we don’t show in the figure), it would trace out a curve known as the income expansion path. This curve always starts at the origin because when income is zero, the consumption of both goods must also be zero. Figure 5.3 shows Meredith’s income expansion path for bus rides and bottled water.

When both goods are normal goods, the income expansion path will be positively sloped because consumption of both goods rises when income does. If the slope of the income expansion path is negative, then the quantity consumed of one of the goods falls with income while the other rises. The one whose quantity falls is an inferior good. Remember that whether a given good is normal or inferior can depend on the consumer’s income level. In Figure 5.3, for example, both bus rides and bottled water are normal goods at incomes up to the level corresponding to the budget constraint containing bundle D. As income rises above that and the budget constraint continues to shift out, the income expansion path begins to curve downward. This outcome means that bus rides become an inferior good as Meredith’s income rises beyond that level. We can also see from the income expansion path that bottled water is never inferior, because the path never curves back to the left. When there are only two goods, it’s impossible for both goods to be inferior at any income level. If they were both inferior, an increase in income would actually lead to lower expenditure on both goods, and the consumer wouldn’t be spending all of her income.

160

The Engel Curve

The income expansion path is a useful tool for examining how consumer behavior changes in response to changes in income, but it has two important weaknesses. First, because we have only two axes, we can only look at two goods at a time. Second, although we can easily see the consumption quantities of each good, we can’t see directly the income level that a particular point on the curve corresponds to. The income level equals the sum of the quantities consumed of each good (which are easily seen in the figure) multiplied by their respective prices (which aren’t easily seen). The basic problem is that when we talk about consumption and income, we care about three numbers—the quantities of each of the two goods and income—but we have only two dimensions on the graph in which to see them.

A better way to see how the quantity consumed of one good varies with income (as opposed to how the relative quantities of the two goods vary) is to take the information conveyed by the income expansion path and plot it on a graph with income on the vertical axis and the quantity of the good in question on the horizontal axis. Panel a of Figure 5.4 shows the relationship between income and the quantity of bus rides from our example. The five points mapped in panel a of Figure 5.4 are the same five consumption bundles represented by points A, B, C, D, and E in Figure 5.3; the only difference between the figures is in the variables measured by the axes.

image
Figure 5.5: Figure 5.4 Engel Curves Show How Consumption Varies with Income
Figure 5.5: (a) In contrast to an income expansion path, an Engel curve compares the consumption of a single good to the consumer’s income. As Meredith’s income increases from $10/week to $25/week, her consumption of bus rides increases from 3 to a little over 6 bus rides. At income levels above $25/week, bus rides are inferior goods, and the number of bus rides she takes decreases.
Figure 5.5: (b) Bottled water is a normal good across all income levels shown here. At an income of $10/week at point A, Meredith consumes 2 bottles of water. At point E, Meredith’s income is $30/week, and the number of bottles of water she buys increases to 9 per week.

161

Engel curve

A curve that shows the relationship between the quantity of a good consumed and a consumer’s income.

The lines traced out in Figure 5.4 are known as Engel curves, named for the nineteenth-century German economist Ernst Engel who first presented the data in this way. Engel curves tell you the quantities of goods—bus rides and bottled water, in this case—that are consumed at each income level. If the Engel curve has a positive slope, the good is a normal good at that income level. If the Engel curve has a negative slope, the good is an inferior good at that income. In Figure 5.4a, bus rides are initially a normal good, but become inferior after bundle D, just as we saw in Figure 5.3. In panel b, bottled water is a normal good at all income levels and the Engel curve is always positively sloped.

Whether the income expansion path or Engel curves are more useful for understanding the effect of income on consumption choices depends on the question. If we care about how the relative quantities of the two goods change with income, the income expansion path is more useful because it shows both quantities at the same time. On the other hand, if we want to investigate the impact of income changes on the consumption of each particular good, the Engel curve is best because it isolates this relationship more clearly. The two curves contain the same information but display it in different ways due to the limitations imposed by having only two axes.

Application: Engel Curves and House Sizes

image
Then
Bernard Hoffman/Time & Life Pictures/Getty Images
image
Now
romakoma/Shutterstock

Houses in the United States have been getting larger for several decades. In 1950, newly built single-family houses had an average of about 1,000 square feet (93 square meters) of floor area, a little less than one-fourth the size of a basketball court. By 2013 the average new house had 2,600 square feet, an all-time high after having dipped slightly during the Great Recession.

Explanations for this trend vary. Some say people’s tastes changed (i.e., they now have different utility functions) in a way that reflects a greater desire for space. Others think that space is a normal good, so homeowners demand more space as they get richer. If this is the case, homeowners’ utility functions didn’t change. Instead, their income increased and that increase moved them to a different part of their utility function where they demand more space.

The numbers are consistent with an income effect. Figure 5.5 plots the average size of newly built homes (in square feet) and average inflation-adjusted household income (in thousands of dollars) from 1973 to 2013. Both house sizes and income rose: income by about 25% and house size by 50%.1

image
Figure 5.6: Figure 5.5 Average New House Size and Household Income in the United States, 1973–2013
Figure 5.6: House sizes and income trended upward between 1973 and 2013, increasing at almost the same rate.

These trends are consistent with income growth driving homeowners to buy larger homes. We should be careful in leaping to this interpretation, though. Many things can trend over time even though they aren’t related. (For example, the coyote population of the United States also increased over the period, but it’s hard to argue that having more coyotes around makes people want larger homes.) And even if income effects matter, other factors might also contribute to the desire for larger homes, such as falling construction costs.

162

It would therefore be nice to have additional evidence about the income–house size relationship that doesn’t involve simple trends over time. Such additional evidence does exist. The American Housing Survey (AHS) is conducted every two years and contains information on housing and demographics for thousands of households. Comparing home sizes to income levels across individual households at a given moment in time should complement our analysis of the average trends above.

We fit a curve relating home size and annual household income in the 2013 survey data (a survey containing about 49,000 households) in Figure 5.6. This is very similar to an Engel curve for home size: It shows how much a household’s purchases of a good (square feet of house) varies with its income.2

image
Figure 5.7: Figure 5.6 Engel Curve for House Size in the United States in 2013
Figure 5.7: The Engel curve for housing slopes upward, indicating that housing is a normal good. However, for incomes between approximately $200,000 and $250,000 per year, house size does not change much as income grows.

We can see that this Engel curve always slopes up. That is, based on these data, house size is always a normal good. However, there is a considerable income range—from about $200,000 to $250,000 a year—where the size of the income effect is fairly small and home size does not change much as income grows. It’s also interesting to compare the average slope of this Engel curve to the size-income correlation we saw in the time trend data. In the time trends in Figure 5.5, 25% income growth was tied to a 50% increase in house size. This relationship is smaller when we look across households in Figure 5.6: People with 10% more income have houses that are around 2% larger. One reason why the relationship across people might be smaller than across time is that the cross section of people includes all houses, not just newly built ones. If home sizes are trending upward over time (which they did from 1950 to 2013), and not just the highest income households are buying new houses, this will reduce the correlation between size and income in the cross section because some higher-income households will be in older, smaller houses. It could also be that factors in addition to income growth (such as preferences) are driving the trends of the past several decades. Nevertheless, it’s clear from both sets of data that income changes are strongly related to the demand for house size.

163

figure it out 5.1

Annika spends all of her income on golf and pancakes. Greens fees at a local golf course are $10 per round. Pancake mix is $2 per box. When Annika’s income is $100 per week, she buys 5 boxes of pancake mix and 9 rounds of golf. When Annika’s income rises to $120 per week, she buys 10 boxes of pancake mix and 10 rounds of golf. Based on these figures, determine whether each of the following statements is true or false, and briefly explain your reasoning.

  1. Golf is a normal good, and pancake mix is an inferior good.

  2. Golf is a luxury good.

  3. Pancakes are a luxury good.

Solution:

  1. A normal good is one of which a consumer buys more when income rises. An inferior good is a good for which consumption falls when income rises. When Annika’s income rises, she purchases more pancake mix and more rounds of golf. This means that both goods are normal goods for Annika. Therefore, the statement is false.

  2. A luxury good has an income elasticity greater than 1. The income elasticity for a good is calculated by dividing the percentage change in quantity demanded by the percentage change in income. Annika’s income rises from $100 to $120. Therefore, the percentage change in income is image . When Annika’s income rises, her consumption of golf changes from 9 rounds to 10. Thus, the percentage change in the quantity of rounds demanded is image . To calculate the income elasticity, we divide the percentage change in quantity by the percentage change in income, image . Golf cannot be a luxury good for Annika because the elasticity is not greater than 1. Therefore, the statement is false.

  3. Again, we must calculate the income elasticity, this time for pancake mix. When Annika’s income rises from $100 to $120 [a 20% rise as calculated in part (b)], Annika increases her purchases of pancake mix from 5 boxes to 10 boxes. Thus, the percentage change in the quantity of pancake mix demanded is image . This means that the income elasticity of demand is image . Because the income elasticity is greater than 1, pancake mix is a luxury good for Annika. Therefore, the statement is true.

164