profit
The difference between a firm’s revenue and its total cost.
We just saw that Ty—
291
There are two basic elements to profit: revenue and cost. In general, these are both affected by a firm’s decisions about how much output to produce and the price it will charge for its output. Because perfectly competitive firms take the market price as given, we only need to focus on the choice of output.
Mathematically, let’s denote the profit a firm makes as π. The profit function is total revenue TR minus total cost TC (each of which is determined by the firm’s output quantity):
π = TR – TC
To figure out the level of output that maximizes profit, think about what happens to total cost and total revenue if the firm decides to produce one additional unit of output. Or, put differently, determine the firm’s marginal cost and marginal revenue.
We know from Chapter 7 that marginal cost is the addition to total cost of producing one more unit of output:
MC = ΔTC/ΔQ
Marginal cost is always greater than zero—
marginal revenue
The additional revenue from selling one additional unit of output.
Revenues equal the good’s price times the quantity produced. A firm’s marginal revenue is the additional revenue it gets from selling one additional unit of output:
MR = ΔTR/ΔQ
A perfectly competitive firm’s marginal revenue is the market price for the good. To see why, remember that these firms can only sell their goods at the market price P. Therefore, the extra revenue they obtain from selling each additional unit of output is P. This is really important, and so we’ll repeat it here: In a perfectly competitive market, marginal revenue equals the market price; that is, MR = P:
Think about what this outcome implies. Total revenue is P × Q. When a firm is a price taker, P does not change no matter what happens to Q. For a price taker, P is a constant, not a function of Q.
This fact means that a perfectly competitive firm’s total revenue is proportional to its output. If output increases by 1 unit, total revenue increases by the price of the product. For this reason, a perfectly competitive firm’s total revenue curve is a straight line from the origin, as shown in Figure 8.2. For example, if Ty sells another dozen eggs, his total revenue rises by the market price of $2.25. And if he keeps selling more, each additional dozen increases total revenue by another $2.25.
As we’ll see in Chapter 9, in market structures other than perfect competition, the price decreases as the quantity the firm produces increases. This introduces an additional factor into our marginal revenue calculation for firms in those other types of markets. The price reduction doesn’t happen in perfectly competitive markets because a firm does not affect the market price with its output choice. So remember, this case of marginal revenue equaling the market price is special: It only applies to firms in perfectly competitive markets.
292
Now that we know the marginal cost and marginal revenue, how does our firm maximize profit in a perfectly competitive market? We know that total cost is always going to rise when output increases (as shown in Figure 8.2)—that is, marginal cost is always positive. Similarly, we know that the firm’s marginal revenue here is constant at all quantities and equal to the good’s market price. The key impact of changing output on the firm’s profit depends on which of these marginal values is larger. If the market price (marginal revenue) is greater than the marginal cost of making another unit of output, then the firm can increase its profit by making and selling another unit, because revenues will go up more than costs. If the market price is less than the marginal cost, the firm should not make the extra unit. The firm will reduce its profit by doing so because while its revenues will rise, they won’t rise as much as its costs. The quantity at which the marginal revenue (price) from selling one more unit of output just equals the marginal cost of making another unit of output is the point at which a firm maximizes its profit. This point occurs at Q* in Figure 8.2. There, the slope of the total revenue curve (the marginal revenue—
MR = P = MC
∂ The appendix at the end of Chapter 9 uses calculus to solve the perfectly competitive firm’s profit-
A firm should increase production as long as revenue increases by more than cost (i.e., when MR = P > MC). Conversely, a firm should decrease production if cost increases by more than revenue (i.e., when MR = P < MC).1
293
It should be clear from this discussion why cost plays such an important role in determining a firm’s output (and this is true for a firm in any type of market structure): It is half of the firm’s profit-
The analysis we’ve just completed shows that the output decision is fairly easy for the firm in a perfectly competitive market: It increases output until marginal cost equals the market price. If marginal cost rises with output—
The P = MC result is extremely useful because, by linking the market price to the firm’s cost curve (or, more precisely, its marginal cost curve), we can determine how a competitive firm’s output changes when the market price changes. Consider a firm with the marginal cost curve shown in Figure 8.3. If the market price is initially P1, then the firm’s demand and marginal revenue curve is horizontal at that price. The firm will maximize profit by setting MR = P1 = MC and producing an output of Q*1. If the market price increases to P2, the firm should increase its production to output Q*2. Why? Because the firm now faces a horizontal demand and marginal revenue curve at P2, it should produce up to the point where marginal cost equals the market price. If price rises to P2 and the firm continues to produce only Q1, it could be selling those units between Q1 and Q*2 at a marginal revenue level (the new market price P2) that is higher than its marginal costs. These extra sales would raise the firm’s profit.
If the market price instead decreases from P1 to P3, the firm should reduce its quantity to Q*3, which has a lower marginal cost equal to P3. If the firm does not make this change, it will be producing those units between Q*3 and Q1 at a loss because marginal revenue for those units would be lower than marginal cost.
You’ve probably heard stories of CEOs who spend firm money on lavish offices, parties, or other perks. While these CEOs enjoy their spending sprees, it seems far-
294
Given such stories, can we really assume that firms maximize profits? It is easiest to see why a small firm would want to maximize profits: Because the manager is usually the owner of the firm, maximizing the firm’s profits directly affects her personally. But larger firms are typically run by people other than the owners. As a result, their managers may be tempted to engage in behavior that does not maximize profits. These profit-
Although managers may sometimes take actions that aren’t profit-
2Steven N. Kaplan and Bernadette A. Minton, “How Has CEO Turnover Changed?” International Review of Finance 12, no. 1 (2012): 57–87.
Profit maximization can probably be driven most directly by strong boards of directors who will confront management on behalf of the shareholders or other companies who are willing to buy up mismanaged firms and replace their executives. Economists Steven Kaplan and Bernadette Minton found evidence of these forces at work among large U.S. companies. The average CEO at these firms had been on the job less than seven years, and Kaplan and Minton found that the likelihood that a CEO stayed on the job was related to how well the company was performing relative to its industry competitors and to companies in other industries. Interestingly, these relationships held whether the CEO’s departure was publicly labeled at the time as forced or unforced—
These forces tend to push wayward managers back toward maximizing profits, as shareholders (the owners of the capital) would desire. Even if these mechanisms fail, the competitive market itself pushes firms to maximize profit. Firms that maximize profits (or get as close to that as possible) will succeed where firms with profit-
A profit-
π = TR – TC
Panel a of Figure 8.4 shows the firm’s average total cost curve, its marginal cost curve, and its demand (marginal revenue) curve. The firm’s total revenue equals the area of the rectangle with height P and base Q*. Its total cost is the area of the rectangle with height ATC* (ATC at the profit-
295
π = TR – TC
= (P × Q) – (ATC × Q)
= (P – ATC) × Q
Therefore, the firm’s profit can be seen in Figure 8.4 as the rectangle with height (P – ATC*) and base equal to the profit-
The profit equation tells us that profit π = (P – ATC) × Q, and profit is positive only when P > ATC*. If P = ATC*, profit is zero, and when P < ATC*, profit is negative. These scenarios are shown in panels b and c of Figure 8.4 . Panel b shows that a firm earns zero profit when P = ATC* = MC. In Chapter 7, we learned that MC = ATC only when ATC is at its minimum. (Remember this fact! It will become very important to us toward the end of this chapter.) Panel c of Figure 8.4 shows a firm earning negative profit because P < ATC*. The obvious question is, why would a firm produce anything at a loss? We answer that question in the next section.
296
See the problem worked out using calculus
Suppose that consumers see haircuts as an undifferentiated good and that there are hundreds of barbershops in the market. The current market equilibrium price of a haircut is $15. Bob’s Barbershop has a daily short-
How many haircuts should Bob give each day if he wants to maximize profit?
If the firm maximizes profit, how much profit will it earn each day?
Solution:
Firms in perfect competition maximize profit by producing the quantity for which P = MC:
P = MC
15 = Q
If Bob gives 15 haircuts and charges $15 for each, the total revenue will be
TR = P × Q
= $15 × 15 = $225
We can use the firm’s total cost function to find the total cost of producing 15 haircuts:
TC = 0.5Q2 = 0.5(15)2 = $112.50
Since profit is TR – TC,
π = $225 – $112.50 = $112.50 per day
If Profit Is Negative, Should a Firm Shut Down? How does a perfectly competitive firm know if it is better off operating at a loss or shutting down and producing zero output? (Remember that shutting down in the short run is not the same thing as exiting the industry, because firms have some fixed costs they still must pay if they shut down in the short run.) The answer (continue to operate at a loss or shut down) depends on the firm’s costs and revenues under each scenario. Table 8.2 shows the information the firm needs to make its decision.
If the firm decides to shut down in the short run and produce nothing, it will have no revenue. But, because it still must pay its fixed cost, its loss will exactly equal that fixed cost:
πshut down = TR – TC = TR – (FC + VC)
= 0 – (FC + 0) = –FC
If the firm continues to operate at a loss in the short run, it will accumulate some revenue, but will have to pay both fixed and variable costs. The profit from operating is the difference between total revenue and fixed and variable costs:
πoperate = TR – TC = TR – FC – VC
Comparing the two profits shows which is better:
πoperate – πshut down = TR – FC – VC – (–FC)
= TR – VC
Therefore, in the short-
297
The operate-
Operate if TR ≥ VC.
Shut down if TR < VC.
Figure 8.5 illustrates these rules. It shows a perfectly competitive firm’s average total cost, average variable cost, marginal cost, and marginal revenue (market price) curves. In the case shown in the figure, the firm is losing money because TR < TC, but it continues to operate because TR > VC. How can we tell this from the figure? We know that TR is the area of a rectangle where P is the height and Q* is the base (TR = P × Q), and VC is the rectangle with height AVC* (AVC at Q*) and base Q* (VC = AVC × Q). Both TR and AVC contain Q*, so this quantity cancels out and plays no role in the operate/shut-
Operate if P ≥ AVC*.
Shut down if P < AVC*.
Therefore, the firm should keep operating as long as the market price is at least as large as its average variable cost at the quantity where price equals its marginal cost. Keep in mind that these rules apply to all firms in all industries in any type of market structure.
See the problem worked out using calculus
For interactive, step-
Cardboard boxes are produced in a perfectly competitive market. Each identical firm has a short-
Solution:
A firm will not produce any output in the short run at any price below its minimum AVC. How do we find the minimum AVC? We learned in Chapter 7 that AVC is minimized when AVC = MC. So, we need to start by figuring out the equation for the average variable cost curve and then solving it for the output that minimizes AVC.
AVC is equal to VC/Q. Remember that total cost is the sum of fixed cost and variable cost:
TC = FC + VC
Fixed cost is that part of total cost that does not vary with output (changes in Q have no effect on FC). Therefore, if TC = 3Q3 – 18Q2 + 30Q + 50, then FC must be 50. This means that VC = 3Q3 – 18Q2 + 30Q. Because AVC = VC/Q,
Next, we find the output for which AVC is at its minimum by equating AVC and MC:
AVC = MC
3Q2 – 18Q + 30 = 9Q2 – 36Q + 30
18Q = 6Q2
18 = 6Q
Q = 3
This means that AVC is at its minimum at an output of 3,000 cardboard boxes per week. To find the level of AVC at this output, we plug Q = 3 into the formula for AVC:
AVC = 3Q2 – 18Q + 30
= 3(3)2 – 18(3) + 30 = 27 – 54 + 30 = $3
Therefore, the minimum price at which the firm should operate is $3. If the price falls below $3, the firm should shut down in the short run and only pay its fixed cost.
298
A tale of three curves
One of the easiest ways to examine the diagrams of cost curves for a perfectly competitive firm is to remember that each of these cost curves tells only a part of the story.
What is the profit-
Is the firm earning a positive profit? The average total cost curve: Once you know the optimal level of output, you can use the average total cost curve to compare price and average total cost to determine whether a firm is earning a positive profit. Profit is measured as the rectangle with a base equal to output and a height equal to the difference between P and ATC at that quantity of output. If a perfectly competitive firm is earning a positive profit, the story ends there. You don’t even need to consider the firm’s average variable cost curve.
Operate or shut down? The average variable cost curve: If a firm is earning a loss (negative profit) because its price is less than its average total cost, the decision of whether or not the firm should continue to operate in the short run depends entirely on the relationship between price and average variable cost. Look at the average variable cost curve to determine how these two variables compare at the profit-
Knowing which curve is used to answer these questions makes it easier to analyze complicated diagrams and answer questions for homework, quizzes, and exams. Remember that each curve has its own role and focus on that curve to simplify your analysis.
299