49
CHAPTER 7
WHY ARE THERE MORE MEMBERS OF A BAND THAN PROFESSORS IN A CLASS?
Diminishing Marginal Returns and the Demand for Labor
Guitarist Eric Clapton was inducted into the Rock & Roll Hall of Fame as a solo artist, and yet he seldom plays alone. He was also inducted into the Hall of Fame as a member of both the Yardbirds and Cream. Ladysmith Black Mambazo tours with 10 singers, whereas their friend Paul Simon often performs solo. Like any employer, bands could always add more people to their workforce or lay a few people off, or a band member could go it alone as a professor does. In this chapter you will learn how these decisions are made, and how rockers and professors differ in spite of the remarkable similarities in their lifestyles, wardrobes, and value to society.
When bandleaders, businesses, and colleges contemplate taking on new personnel, they want to know what hiring additional workers could do for them. The contribution of 1 more worker to the level of output per period is called the marginal product of labor. If adding a professor at a college with 100 professors allows 30 more students to be taught each year, the marginal product of the 101st professor is 30 students per year. If another barista (coffee bartender) at Starbucks allows the store to serve 12 more lattes per hour, those 12 lattes are the last-
50
In the classic film Mary Poppins, actor Dick Van Dyke becomes a one-
1 See www.onemanband.org.
If going from 1 to 2 workers allows 1 person to get really good at making drinks while the other person can develop cash register and cleanup efficiency, the marginal product of the second worker can exceed that of the first. On working-joe.com, the staff of Working Joe Espresso suggests that a worker with divided attention can serve 10 drinks an hour, whereas a focused barista can serve 40 drinks an hour. The marginal product of the first worker is 10 because the total product increases from 0 to 10 when the first worker is hired. The second hire allows 1 person to focus on espresso-
Alas, marginal product can’t keep increasing forever. According to the “law” of diminishing marginal returns, as more of one input—
In accordance with the law of diminishing marginal returns, the path of marginal benefits from myriad economic pursuits turns downward sooner or later. Efficiency dictates that each activity should be carried out until the marginal benefit no longer exceeds the marginal cost, and it is the fall of marginal benefits that brings a halt to many a virtuous endeavor. Other chapters in this book discuss how the marginal utility that consumers seek and the marginal revenue that firms seek generally fall. Marginal product falls sooner or later, too, as opportunities for specialization run out, redundancy sets in, and the usefulness of fixed inputs (such as stages, espresso bars, and classrooms) is spread thin by growing quantities of variable inputs (such as musicians, baristas, and professors).
Let’s extend the previous section’s example of the espresso bar, in which the marginal product is 10 for the first worker and 30 for the second. The accompanying table presents production levels for each quantity of workers. With 1 person already working the cash register and another working the espresso machine, a third worker may be useful for keeping beverage ingredients stocked and helping to make drinks, contributing a marginal product of 20. A fourth worker wouldn’t have a lot of equipment to work with but could increase sales by 15 espressos per hour by covering other workers’ breaks, wiping tables, and helping the other workers stay focused on their specialized roles. A fifth worker would have less important tasks to complete but might increase sales by 5 espressos per hour by helping to take customer orders, checking in new shipments, and washing dishes. In similar ways, diminishing marginal product would be observed as more band members were added to a stage with a fixed number of instruments and as more professors were added to a fixed number of classrooms. Notice in the table that total product increases even as marginal product decreases; any positive marginal product represents a contribution to the total level of production.
51
Can marginal product be negative? Yes, indeed: At some point another worker simply gets in the way. A second barista at the drive-
WORKERS | MARGINAL PRODUCT OF LABOR | TOTAL PRODUCT OF LABOR |
1 | 10 | 10 |
2 | 30 | 40 |
3 | 20 | 60 |
4 | 15 | 75 |
5 | 5 | 80 |
Seventy-
With a hundred and ten cornets close at hand.
They were followed by rows and rows of the finest virtuosos—
The cream of every famous band.
—From “76 Trombones” in The Music Man
Not all bands, espresso bars, colleges, and factories are alike. The rate at which marginal product decreases depends on the situation and the amount of the fixed input. There may be 76 trombones in the big parade, but a folksinger can sing and play the guitar with little need for accompaniment. One player cannot make an orchestra, however, and the marginal product of the players needed to fill out the critical strings, brass, percussion, and woodwind sections is large. The contribution of a guitarist, backup vocalist, or drummer for singer Alanis Morrisette is positive but not so large. If you’re looking for really big sound, consider William Havergal Brian’s “Gothic” symphony (Symphony No. 1, 1919–
52
Why does guitarist Keith Richards appear with Mick Jagger and the other Rolling Stones, whereas Brandeis University professor and former U.S. Labor Secretary Robert Reich takes the stage alone at his lectures? It’s not because additional professors cost more than additional rock stars; it’s because additional professors contribute less than additional rockers do. That is, professors’ marginal product plummets as more of them are added. The first professor brings intellectual intrigue to the audience. A second professor at a lecture could perhaps take over the diagram-
No employer wants to hire another worker after marginal product has become negative, meaning that additional workers will actually reduce output levels. However, there’s a big difference between negative marginal product and diminishing marginal product. Employers generally do want to keep hiring after marginal product starts falling. The important reason is that any positive marginal product represents a contribution to total product. Employers are wise to keep hiring as long as the marginal product of an additional worker brings in at least as much money as that worker must be paid.
The amount of money that an additional worker brings in is found by multiplying the marginal product of that worker by the marginal revenue of the good or service (meaning the additional dollars gained from each new unit sold). If another band member increases CD sales by 1,000 and each CD sells for $10, that last-
Consider an espresso bar whose first 5 workers have marginal products of 10, 30, 20, 15, and 5 drinks per hour, respectively. If each espresso sells for $2, the marginal revenue product for these workers is $20, $60, $40, $30, and $10 per hour, respectively. If the wage rate is $12 per hour, 4 workers should be hired. The revenues generated by the first 4 workers exceed their $12 cost per hour, but there’s no sense in paying $12 for a fifth worker who will only bring in $10!
The demand for workers is linked directly to the demand for products. If the demand for espresso increases and drives the price up to $3 per espresso, the marginal revenue product of the first 5 workers will increase to $30, $90, $60, $45, and $15 per hour, respectively. With this higher demand for espresso, the fifth worker will be worthwhile to hire because he or she will bring in $15 worth of sales for a $12 wage. Because the demand for labor is based on the marginal revenue product of labor (the marginal product of labor times the output price), and the output price component of marginal revenue product is derived from the demand for the output, the demand for inputs is called a derived demand.
53
This chapter explains the reasons for diminishing marginal product and provides several real-
If you’ve spent much time in a rowboat, you’ve probably seen that 1 person can row gently down the stream at about 2 mph. With 2 rowers in a boat with 2 oars, each can take an oar and the speed may increase to 3 mph, making the marginal product of the second rower a 1-
Diminishing marginal product affects everything from the speed of our progress while rowing to the decision about how many musicians the folk band Beggars Row should hire. And no matter what your economics professor’s ratings are on www.ratemyprofessor.com, a second professor in the same classroom probably wouldn’t be nearly as valuable.
In what situations have you seen diminishing marginal product in action?
Have you ever seen an employee who added nothing to the productivity of a business? Why do you suppose such workers are sometimes hired?
If you were the president of a consulting firm, how would you decide how many consultants to hire? Please be specific.
What could explain the fact that the band White Stripes has 2 members and the band Linkin Park has 6 members?
Imagine you are the owner of an espresso bar. Your first 5 workers have hourly marginal products of 10, 30, 20, 15, and 5 drinks, respectively, as in the example used in the chapter. You can sell as many espressos as you want for $1 each, labor constitutes the only nonnegligible marginal cost of selling espressos, and the wage rate in your area is $8 per hour. How many employees would you hire for your bar?