CHAPTER 8
COULD THE FUTURE COST OF ENERGY CHANGE LIFE AS WE KNOW IT?
Production Costs and the Inescapable Demand for Energy
Researchers at the Post Carbon Institute (www.postcarbon.org), a nonprofit energy think tank, suggest that energy costs will increase dramatically as the supply of fossil fuels (oil, coal, and natural gas) decreases.1 Among other things, skyrocketing energy costs would spell doom for transportation systems and the suburban neighborhoods, shopping malls, factories, and schools they serve. Energy costs are already built into the price of almost everything we buy because energy is consumed in the production, transportation, use, and disposal of most products. A spike in oil prices in the 1970s was followed by double-
1 This view is shared by other groups. The U.S. Army Corps of Engineers reports that once oil production peaks, “geopolitics and market economics will result in even more significant price increases and security risks” (see www.cecer.army.mil/
At present, energy from renewable sources, such as the sun, wind, earth (geothermal), plants (biodiesel), and water (hydroelectric), costs significantly more than energy from fossil fuels. Even with the cheap stuff, 29 million households are eligible for financial help from the federal Low Income Home Energy Assistance Program (LIHEAP), and home energy costs take about 17 percent of the income of LIHEAP recipients (www.liheap.org/
Energy is the amount of physical work a system is capable of performing. Power is the rate of energy transfer per unit of time. The first law of thermodynamics implies that energy cannot be created, consumed, or destroyed because the amount of energy in the universe is fixed. Thus, energy “production” refers not to the creation of energy but to its conversion into a usable form, and energy “use” does not mean that energy is destroyed but that it is dissipated into heat or other unusable forms.
Most of our efforts to harness energy for commercial electricity production involve making turbines spin to create electrical currents. Nuclear fission and coal combustion create steam that turns turbines. Wind and flowing water apply direct force on turbines. You may have created electricity yourself by turning a crank or a bicycle wheel rigged for that purpose. An exception is solar energy collected by a photovoltaic cell, which converts light energy into direct-
The sun is the original and ultimate source of energy, fueling the plant life that feeds other living things, as well as the ancient plant life whose fossilized remains are burned as oil, natural gas, and coal. The water wheel was invented in 350 C.E. as a way to capture energy from flowing water. Windmills were used to harness wind energy beginning about 950 C.E. James Watt used wood and coal fires to power the first modern steam engine in 1765, and to this day the standard unit of power, equal to 1/746 of a horsepower, or 1 amp times 1 volt, bears his last name. Gottlieb Daimler inaugurated the gasoline-
Rocky Mountain Institute founder Amory Lovins describes two paths for energy dependence. The first is a “soft path” of many renewable energy sources, such as solar panels on millions of roofs or wind turbines on thousands of “wind farms.” The second is a “hard path” of relatively few centralized fossil-
In 1850, the United States obtained most of its energy from decentralized sources—
Like the demand for labor, the demand for energy is derived from the demand for the services this input provides. Industry creates 32 percent of U.S. energy demand, transportation creates 30 percent, residential users create 20 percent, and commercial users create 18 percent.2 Global growth in the number of homes, businesses, industrial plants, and vehicles leads to corresponding increases in the demand for energy.
2 See www.eia.doe.gov/
Much of the energy that is tapped by consumers literally goes up in smoke or is lost to heat or respiration. Energy conversion efficiency refers to the percentage of energy from a source that is converted into useful energy rather than being spent in the process of making energy useful. Wind turbines convert about 30 percent of the wind’s energy into electricity. Coal-
3 For example, see www.spectrolab.com/
Sometimes the power goes out entirely. On August 14, 2003, an estimated 50 million people in eight U.S. states and the Canadian province of Ontario lost power, in some areas for up to 4 days. Estimates of the financial burden of this blackout in the United States approach $10 billion. Canadians lost 18.9 million work hours, and manufacturing shipments in Ontario fell by $1.9 billion. A U.S.–Canadian government investigation placed blame for the massive blackouts on the cascading effects of operators’ mistakes, computer failures, rule violations, and inadequate equipment maintenance by FirstEnergy Corporation of Ohio. For many, this event was a wake-
In 2006, Americans spent almost 9 percent of gross domestic product, amounting to more than $1 trillion, on energy.4 Energy costs also include important environmental and health costs, which are addressed in Chapter 29. Here we examine the cost structure of energy production for large and small electricity producers. Several critical types of cost are explained in this context. Their meanings are summarized here for convenience:
Fixed cost: a cost that does not change as more of the product is made
Variable cost: a cost that increases as more of the product is made
Total cost: fixed costs plus variable costs
Marginal cost: the cost of making 1 more unit of the product
Average fixed cost: the total fixed cost divided by the number of units made
Average variable cost: the total variable cost divided by the number of units made
The cost structure in an energy market depends on the scale of the production facilities, which tends to be either very large or very small. The 16,000-
Mr. Volkmeier installed 10 165-
Let’s consider the cost picture for energy producers, such as Mr. Volkmeier. The $2,500 cost of the equipment—
The determination of the best number of panels for Mr. Volkmeier requires a closer look at marginal cost and marginal benefit. We know that, in general, marginal cost is the cost to producers of 1 more unit of a good. The marginal benefit for producers is the marginal revenue—the additional revenue they take in from 1 more unit. As explained in Chapter 1, if something is worth doing, it should be done until the marginal benefit no longer exceeds the marginal cost, and that holds true for producers as well: If it is worthwhile to produce a good or service, it should be produced until marginal cost equals marginal revenue.
Marginal cost is closely tied to marginal product, although the two measures move in opposite directions. As explained in Chapter 7, the marginal product of labor generally increases and then decreases. In such cases, marginal cost falls and then rises. The explanation is straightforward: As marginal product increases for the first few workers, it takes fewer additional workers to make another unit of output, so the marginal cost of making that additional output falls. As the marginal product of workers falls, it takes more workers and thus more wage payments to make more units, and marginal cost increases. Likewise, as the marginal product of solar panels decreases as a result of roof crowding, it takes more additional panels to increase energy capacity by a given amount, and the marginal cost of energy capacity increases.
Let’s track Mr. Volkmeier’s marginal cost as he decides how many solar panels to install. Given the capacity of individual panels, in this example we will consider 165-
Average fixed cost is total fixed cost divided by the quantity of output. To find the average fixed cost of producing 165 watts of capacity, we divide the total fixed cost of $2,500 by 165 and find $15.15. As output increases, average fixed cost invariably decreases because the same total fixed cost is divided by a larger and larger quantity. For example, the average fixed costs of producing capacities of 330, 825, and 1,100 watts are $7.57, $3.03, and $2.27, respectively. When a capacity of 250,000 watts is being produced, the average fixed cost is 1 cent.
Average variable cost is the cost of the variable input (panels) divided by the quantity of output (watts). Suppose that the first 4 panels have prime locations in the sun, the next 4 create 50 percent obstruction for other panels, the 4 after that must go on the side with one-
Producers compare average total cost with price to determine whether profits or losses are in store. Average total cost is the sum of average fixed cost and average variable cost. It can also be found by dividing total cost by the quantity of output. Because the total cost of producing 330 watts is ($2,500 + [2 × $600]) = $3,700, the average total cost is $3,700/330 = $11.21. Likewise, the average total cost of producing 825 and 1,100 watts is $7.39 and $7.72, respectively.
The accompanying table summarizes the marginal and average cost levels. Notice that as output increases, the average total cost decreases and then increases. Average total cost will generally fall as output increases at small levels of production because decreases in average fixed cost are initially dramatic (for example, going from 1 watt to 2 watts cuts the average fixed costs down from $2,500 to $1,250), and these decreases are larger than the increases in average variable cost. At higher output levels, average fixed cost decreases more gradually than average variable cost increases, and average total cost begins to rise at precisely the quantity at which marginal cost rises above average total cost.
WATTS | MARGINAL COST | AVERAGE FIXED COST | AVERAGE VARIABLE COST | AVERAGE TOTAL COST |
330 | $ 3.64 | $7.57 | $3.64 | $11.21 |
825 | $ 7.27 | $3.03 | $4.36 | $ 7.39 |
1,100 | $10.90 | $2.27 | $5.45 | $ 7.72 |
With millions of small producers of identical units of energy, the energy market would resemble the perfectly competitive model that Adam Smith described as being efficient, as discussed in Chapter 6. In such a market, it would be impossible for any one producer to maintain a price for energy in excess of average cost because competitors would be willing and available to sell energy for a price as low as average cost. However, the energy market in the United States does not, in fact, resemble the competitive model.
Eleven hundred coal-
Although there is diminishing marginal product from coal and uranium, the overarching cost of these types of operations is the cost of building the power plants themselves. The enormous fixed cost of these facilities makes the cost structure of coal-
The fixed costs of coal and nuclear power are prohibitive for any modest level of production. A competitive market divided among many coal or nuclear power producers could not survive because none of the plants would sell enough energy to cover fixed costs. The only way for such a plant to break even is to serve a large region and to sell mass quantities of electricity. When high fixed costs effectively eliminate access to the market by competing firms, the result is a natural monopoly—a single firm that is more efficient than any number of competitive firms would be. Water utilities are also natural monopolies because the enormous cost of a water system infrastructure causes average fixed cost to eclipse marginal and average variable costs; the solutions described in the next section apply similarly to water suppliers.
Our reliance on natural monopolies for power raises the prospects for regulation to achieve both monopoly production and moderated prices simultaneously. As explained in Chapter 7, competition keeps prices in check, whereas a monopoly can garner lasting profits at the expense of consumers. The importance of energy to production, transportation, food supplies, and winter heating, among other essentials, makes price moderation a concern of government legislators. Given that a monopoly will exist naturally, regulation can limit prices and increase output. By restricting prices to the level of average cost, lawmakers can ensure that consumers pay the smallest amount possible without sending the power utility into debt.
Regulations must be applied and removed with care. In the summer of 2000, people in California began to experience an electricity shortage after power plants in that state were deregulated and sold to private energy wholesalers. The wholesale price of power was uncapped, but limits remained on retail prices. Thus, the power utilities purchased power from the deregulated wholesalers and sold it to customers at regulated retail prices. As cold snaps and heat waves increased electricity demand, production was constrained by plant closings and by increased temperatures that caused more precipitation to fall as rain rather than snow, leaving less snowmelt to fuel hydroelectric power stations.
Increased demand and decreased supply caused the wholesale energy prices in California to exceed the regulated retail prices. The inability to pass higher costs on to consumers resulted in electricity shortages and multibillion-
Energy can be produced centrally by natural monopolies using fossil fuels or uranium, or locally by small producers of energy from alternative sources. There has been considerable interest and growth in alternative fuels during the past several decades, but, pollution costs aside, fossil fuels are still far less expensive and provide the large majority of energy in the United States. Dwindling stocks of oil and coal, dilemmas over the safe and secure storage of nuclear waste, ethical interests in conserving energy resources for future generations, and the demands of worldwide development force users to grapple with the spectrum of energy options. The high fixed costs of hard-
The Castle River Wind Farm in Alberta, Canada, operates 67 wind turbines and produces 125 million kilowatt-
According to warnings from the Post Carbon Institute, fossil-
Which of the following power sources are most likely to come from natural monopolies? Which could be set up either as centralized power sources or as decentralized, soft-
wind turbines
hydroelectric power generation along a river
coal
oil
solar
nuclear
Of the six types of costs discussed in this chapter, which type is the most important to the decision as to how much of a good or service to produce? Why?
Draw supply-