119
CHAPTER 17
SHOULD DAMAGE AWARDS IN LAWSUITS BE CAPPED?
Benefits and Costs of Limiting the Burden of Litigation
A doctor in Kentucky who stands accused of negligence in what he calls a frivolous malpractice lawsuit described his ordeal this way: As he struggles through the prolonged litigation, he works for several months each year simply to cover his six-
The husband of a woman in Michigan who died as a result of what he calls a missed diagnosis described his ordeal this way: As his sons struggle with the absence of their mother, he works through the loss of his life partner. He sees malpractice litigation as a needed inducement for attentive medical care. He doesn’t enjoy his time at home the way he used to. What with the stress of single parenthood, the expense, the lost sleep, and the loss of faith in humanity, the quality of his life has gone downhill.
This doctor and this widower represent two valid sides of a debate that affects thousands of Americans who are involved in negligence lawsuits. The consequences of litigation are grave, as are the repercussions of human error. Is uncapped litigation a prudent and effective inducement to minimize error? We can invoke the economic way of thinking to guide public policy and foster virtuous litigation with checks on its emotional burden, frequency, and expense.
120
Since the 1960s, a fruitful collaboration between legal scholars and economists has fashioned the new subfield of law and economics. To the analysis of law, economists lend tools with which to seek the optimal level of litigation, create incentive structures for swift and fair resolution of disputes, and evaluate schemes for punishment. The growing discipline of law and economics now boasts national and international professional associations and prominent journals as testaments to the popularity of applying economic reasoning to legal issues.
Consider disputes over liability for product failures. The challenge is to decide whether the manufacturer of a product that has caused harm, such as a soda bottle that exploded, an oil tanker that spilled oil, or an airplane that crashed, should be held responsible for the injuries. Courts now embrace “risk–
the usefulness of the product to the user and society as a whole
the likelihood and degree of injury involved
the availability of safer products that serve the same purpose
the manufacturer’s ability to make the product safer without making it prohibitively expensive
the user’s ability to avoid harm by exercising care
the user’s likely awareness of the inherent dangers
the manufacturer’s ability to spread the burden of liability by charging higher prices or carrying liability insurance
The court adopted this procedure in the case of a helicopter pilot who noticed a loss of oil pressure and attempted an emergency landing. Fog in the area caused the landing to go awry: The helicopter crashed, and the passengers and crew were seriously injured. It turned out that the loss of oil pressure resulted from a loose oil-
1 See www.avweb.com/
Economic reasoning can be applied to legal issues in countless ways; the remainder of this chapter focuses on the economics of damage awards in tort litigation. A tort is a private wrong, or a wrongful act that—
121
It would be grand if we could do away with lawsuits—
Financial damage awards in legal cases provide a countervailing incentive to manufacture safer products, to make streets and sidewalks safe, and to spend more time examining and treating each patient. Although most tort claims do not reach trial, it is the threat of damage awards at trial that motivates out-
The existence of damage awards can encourage safety precautions, and when that fails, such awards can help victims recoup their losses. Court cases involving accidental shootings offer a dramatic example. As of 1995, no major gun manufacturer included an internal lock in its guns to prevent accidental or unauthorized use. In that year, victims of accidental shootings began filing lawsuits against gun manufacturers to challenge the inadequacy of safety features on guns. Today, although no federal statute requires internal locks, more than a dozen gun makers offer guns with internal locks. The entire line of handguns made by Taurus Firearms, for example, features internal locks. The Brady Campaign to Prevent Gun Violence2 describes this trend as “the most significant safety advance in firearm design in decades,” and its members worry that legislation limiting the liability of gun manufacturers would eliminate the incentive for manufacturers to implement such safety-
2 See www.bradycampaign.org.
In the 2002 case of Grunow vs. Valor Corp. of Florida, a West Palm Beach jury awarded $24 million to the widow of a teacher who had been shot and killed by a middle school student. The jury placed 45 percent of the blame on the school board because the student was able to enter campus with a gun; 50 percent on the owner of the gun, who kept it in an unlocked drawer; and 5 percent on the gun distributor, who was found negligent for supplying the gun without appropriate safety measures.
We’d like to think that people would never place time, money, or other interests ahead of risks to health and life. Consider, however, the number of deaths that could be avoided with adequate care. In a typical year in the United States, about 43,000 people die in motor vehicle crashes, 29,000 die in incidents involving firearms, and 20,000 die as the result of illnesses associated with sexual behavior (primarily HIV, hepatitis B and C, and cervical cancer).3 It takes time to label medicines legibly and to check labels carefully, and an Institute of Medicine study estimates that 7,000 U.S. deaths are caused by medication errors each year. The United States Pharmacopoeia, the official public standards-
3 See Ali H. Mokdad et al., “Actual Causes of Death in the United States, 2000,” Journal of the American Medical Association (2004), 291, 1238–
122
In previous chapters, it was explained that the burden of even a small risk of large losses is intolerable. For instance, despite the roughly 1-
Most businesses, doctors, governments, and schools can’t afford the small-
4 See www.acog.org.
5 See www.msms.org/
Don’t think that doctors, institutions, and firms are the only ones paying the cost of litigation. Even if you stay far afield from litigation, you pay a share of the costs. The litigation burden is woven into the prices paid for health care, education, and almost every product or service. An organization called Citizens against Lawsuit Abuse in Orange County, California, claims that every year nearly $1,200 in litigation costs is passed on to each U.S. consumer.6 Before the closing of the Clark forklift manufacturing plant in Danville, Kentucky, company executives explained that $1,000 of the price of each forklift went to cover litigation expenses.
6 See www.occala.org/
As important as the tort system is to decisions that promote safety and health, there may be too much of a good thing. The potential for large damage awards provides incentives for frivolous lawsuits as well as meritorious ones, and some steps taken to avoid litigation have unfortunate results. We can live with the sporadic loss of homecoming parades, Junior Achievement birdhouse projects, and diving boards at hotel pools for fear of litigation; it is of greater concern when doctors shy away from high-
123
Opponents to legal reform correctly argue that most lawsuits are settled out of court, plaintiffs often lose, and many exorbitant damage awards are reduced on appeal. For example, when a jury awarded an Alabama couple $581 million in punitive damages and $975,000 for mental anguish because they were overcharged $1,200 for the installation of two satellite dishes, the trial court reduced the award to $300 million and the case was settled. Even when settlement occurs or plaintiffs get nothing at trial, however, the legal wrangling can take many years, cause many tears, and cost fortunes.
A large body of economic literature suggests that people respond to incentives in rational ways. The trick is to find the best ways to deliver incentives that reduce frivolous lawsuits and bring disputing parties to swift and fair resolutions. England is among many countries with loser-
7 See Thomas D. Rowe, Jr., and David A. Anderson, “One-
President George W. Bush and many state legislators have endorsed a $250,000 cap on damage awards. By limiting awards for pain and suffering, caps can rein in the limitless uncertainty of litigation. States with such caps have experienced relatively slow growth in medical malpractice insurance premiums. The problem with a cap at that level is that it erodes desired incentives for safety and prevents adequate compensation for victims of the worst harms. A $250,000 award might be acceptable for a lost limb but not for a lost life. Or as Senator Edward M. Kennedy (D-
8 See www.latimes.com/
Damage caps reduce uncertainty but threaten unfair treatment of those who receive the worst injuries. An attractive solution is to set relatively high caps that differ according to the type of injury received. For example, caps on noneconomic damages for each type of injury could be set at the 95th percentile of awards granted over the past 10 years. That means that, if the future resembled the past, only the highest 5 percent of awards for even the worst injuries would be affected by the caps. The cap might be $50,000 for a lost finger and $5 million for a lost life. These caps would allow courts the latitude to grant more compensation to those who suffer more but would eliminate awards in the hundreds of millions or billions of dollars.
124
High, graduated caps would permit the incentives and justice of most awards. They would allow potential defendants, including drivers, home and business owners, coaches, and teachers, to sleep easier knowing that a mind-
Spurred by the importance of economic incentives in our litigious society, the new subfield of law and economics is changing the way people think about legal policy. Lawsuits create tremendous benefits and tragic costs; the optimal level of litigation would include only those cases from which the benefit exceeds the cost. There is widespread belief that current caseloads include frivolous lawsuits, meaning that the optimal level has been exceeded, but a moderate volume of litigation would promote safety and justice well worth the cost. If that’s true, public policy should focus on reducing the burden of lawsuits and dispensing with baseless cases, without undermining the incentives, restitution, and accountability that protect society from selfishness run amok.
Caps on damages would reduce the risk burden of litigation by eliminating the possibility of awards that eclipse common expectations. Graduated caps could achieve these goals without limiting severely injured individuals to the same maximum award as those whose injuries are less serious. Reduced awards would also decrease the incentives to litigate and, therefore, the volume of litigation, as would loser-
9 See, for example, www.whitehouse.gov/
There is no consensus among economists about whether caps on damages are warranted, but the economic way of thinking helps narrow the advisable options. Graduated caps provide a viable compromise between the weighty risk burden of uncapped awards and the inefficient incentives and unjust compensation provided by a single modest cap.
Has anyone you know been involved in a lawsuit? With respect to that case or to any other lawsuit with which you are familiar, discuss the incentives that existed for the claim to be filed, for the case to be settled out of court, and for avoidance of the type of behavior that allegedly caused the harm.
125
Do you think it is common for people to place selfish interests ahead of safety precautions? How often do you hear of people drinking and driving? Creating secondhand smoke? Selling drugs?
As we consider public policy to promote responsible behavior, are there any particular professions that deserve attention? Do physicians, educators, and religious leaders have adequate incentives to uphold appropriate standards of conduct? If not, provide examples that support your belief that people in these positions might act selfishly and need outside incentives to behave virtuously.
Are there particular professions in which the incentives for proper conduct are excessive? What examples can you provide?
Explain your own stance on the prudence of placing caps on legal damages. What specific plan would you implement if you had the authority?