126
CHAPTER 18
WHAT’S TO LOVE ABOUT TAXES?
Free Riding on Public Goods, Deadweight Loss, and the Lesser of Two Evils
The Stamp Act of 1765 required American colonists to pay taxes to Great Britain for all newspapers, legal documents, commercial contracts, licenses, pamphlets, and playing cards. What rubbed colonists the wrong way was not taxation as such but the fact that they were taxed without having direct representation in the British Parliament. American colonists’ tax dollars were going toward things that they cared little about, such as paying down Britain’s debt after the French and Indian War and supporting British troops who were posted to “protect” the colonies. The Tea Act of 1773 was the last straw, spurring the Boston Tea Party and helping to spark the Revolutionary War. The Tea Act actually reduced taxes and trade barriers for tea imported from the British East India Company, lowering tea prices for colonists. The taxes had been beneficial, however, to colonial tea merchants who sold tea smuggled from Holland. Lower taxes on British tea left little room for competition and gave the East India Company a virtual monopoly on tea sales.
After winning the Revolutionary War, the Americans passed tax legislation as one of the first steps in forming the United States, and taxation is now a favored means of providing public goods throughout the world. We all love to hate taxes, but in our zeal to get the tax man off our backs, we might make missteps if we don’t step back and consider the wisdom as well as the woes of this exercise in pooling money. This chapter examines some of the pros and cons of taxation.
127
Chapter 11 introduced the concept of public goods—those goods that anyone can use without paying for them and which rational wealth maximizers would not voluntarily purchase because they can free ride on the purchases of other people. Taxes are the ticket to adequate funding for public goods, such as police, parks, firefighters, national forests, national defense, public transportation, public schools, prisons, courts, environmental protection, and disaster relief. People tend to take public goods for granted, but they form the foundation for civilization as we know it, and taxes are simply the way of paying for them.
Taxes are about cooperation to achieve a greater good. The incentive is for individuals to evade taxes and free ride, but the Internal Revenue Service is in the business of balancing that incentive with the prospects of fines and imprisonment. There are many calls for lower tax rates as a route to fatter wallets without the risk of punishment. The bad news is that tax cuts can necessitate erosion in the provision of public goods, and public goods can be a tremendous bargain. When a neighborhood of 100 homes pools funds for a playground and tennis courts, each family has these services at 1/100th of the cost of building its own playground and courts. When 100 million taxpayers pitch in to pay for the U.S. Centers for Disease Control and Prevention,1 for a tiny fraction of the cost of a noncooperative approach, the country receives better disease prevention services than individual efforts could provide.
1 See www.cdc.gov.
Virtually every society on earth has grappled with the concept of taxation and decided it’s a keeper. In ancient times, scribes collected taxes for the Egyptian pharaohs. The ancient Athenians imposed a monthly tax, called a metoikion, on immigrants. Caesar Augustus provided retirement funds for protectors of the Roman Empire by levying an inheritance tax. After Rome fell, the Saxon kings imposed custom duties and property taxes.
As useful as taxes appear to be, voters gobble up promises of lower taxes. The cliché is that, if elected, new politician X will lower taxes without reducing services by cleaning house and eliminating the wasteful inefficiencies of government bureaucracy. Greater frugality is a virtuous goal, but after the election, politician X generally has a much harder time finding and eliminating waste than was suggested in campaign rhetoric. Soon after taking office in 2004, California governor Arnold Schwarzenegger kept his promises to revoke the car tax, freeze state spending, and audit the state budget. Rather than finding enough painless ways to tighten up the budget, the trade-
Taxes can achieve great things, but that doesn’t mean that all taxes are good, that higher taxes would be better, or that any taxes come without their own troubles. As a student of the economic way of thinking, you know that each particular tax should be evaluated in terms of its costs and benefits, and taxes should be raised or lowered until an additional dollar collected will cause more harm than good. Among many potential pitfalls, taxes can be misused, too high or low, unfair, or inefficient.
128
When contemplating new taxes during the Civil War, Senator Garrett Davis pronounced that the guiding principles of taxation should include “the idea that taxes shall be paid according to the abilities of a person to pay.” If it is proper for people who earn more to pay more, how much more should they pay?
A progressive tax obligates people with low incomes to pay smaller proportions of their incomes in taxes than people with high incomes do. For example, the Tax Act of 1862, signed by President Abraham Lincoln to help pay for the Civil War, collected 3 percent of income more than $600 and 5 percent of income more than $10,000.2 Like the current U.S. income tax, the 1862 tax collected a relatively large share of large incomes and was, therefore, progressive.
2 See www.taxworld.org/
A proportional tax represents the same proportion of every person’s income. At the end of the Civil War the tax laws were changed to require a flat 5 percent of income from all taxpayers. A flat tax is proportional because each person pays the same proportion (in this case 5 percent) of his or her income in taxes. A flat tax can be transformed into a progressive tax by making an initial amount of earnings tax free. The post–
A regressive tax obligates people with low incomes to pay a larger proportion of their income in taxes than people with high incomes do. For example, in 1643 the British Parliament imposed taxes on essential commodities, such as grain and meat, to pay for the army commanded by Oliver Cromwell. This excise tax was regressive because the poor devote a larger share of their income to essential commodities than the rich do. That is, a person who earns $4,000 per year might spend 75 percent of that income ($3,000) on food, whereas a person who earns $40,000 might spend only 15 percent ($6,000) on food. If there were a 5 percent tax rate on food purchases, the lower-
Chapter 9 explained that deadweight loss is loss that, unlike any sort of transfer from one person to another, does not become anyone else’s gain. Taxation is a potential source of deadweight loss. Tax revenues themselves represent transfers from taxpayers to the government. However, when goods and services are taxed, fewer of them are bought and sold, the result being a loss of the net gains that would otherwise be received from units not sold because of the tax. Consider the example of airline tickets. Suppose that, in the absence of taxes, the equilibrium price for a round-
3 The law of diminishing marginal returns implies that marginal cost decreases as quantity decreases.
129
Regardless of who actually sends the tax payment to the government, the tax burden is typically shared between customers who pay more than the no-
The Joint Economic Committee of the U.S. Congress reports that each additional dollar of income taxes collected creates a deadweight loss of 25 cents.4 The deadweight loss created by a tax is often unavoidable, but policymakers decide that the loss is outweighed by the benefit of the tax. There are also ways to craft tax plans that minimize or eliminate deadweight loss. When consumers will purchase the same quantity of a good at any price, as might be expected for a lifesaving medication that has no substitutes, the demand is described as perfectly inelastic and the demand curve is vertical. If a $10 tax on heart medicine did not change the quantity purchased because of inelastic demand, no deadweight loss would result because there is no reduction in consumption and, therefore, no loss of surplus. The manufacturer would not need to absorb any of the tax burden because the consumers would pay any price for the product, and the $10 tax revenue would come entirely from patients and would exactly offset the lost consumer surplus. A tax on heart medicine may be unpopular, but the same logic applies to taxes on, say, cigarettes, whose addictive qualities create demand that is inelastic, though not perfectly inelastic.
4 See www.house.gov/
A lump-
130
Fans of efficiency praise lump-
Income taxes, collected as a percentage of earnings, generate more than $1 trillion in annual revenue for the U. S. government. For single taxpayers, the Internal Revenue Service collects 10 percent of the first $6,000 of taxable income, 15 percent of the next $20,500, 25 percent of the next $37,250, 28 percent of the next $70,000, 33 percent of the next $156,000, and 35 percent of all additional income (these dollar values are approximate). The rising marginal tax rates make this tax progressive. In practice, the progressivity of the tax depends not only on the tax rates but also on the abilities of taxpayers at various income levels to shelter their earnings from taxation by taking advantage of legal exemptions and deductions. Billionaire Leona Helmsley is infamous for saying, “Only the little people pay taxes.” But then, Helmsley went to prison for tax evasion, so the little people got the last laugh.
A sales tax is collected as a percentage of payments for purchases. The United States currently has no national sales tax; state sales tax rates range from 7.25 percent in California to 0 in Alaska, Delaware, Montana, New Hampshire, and Oregon. Sales taxes are regressive because relatively rich people devote more of their wealth to saving and investment and spend a smaller share of their income. Most states exempt food from sales taxes, a policy that reduces the regressivity of the tax. A fixed sales-
5 See www.willamette.edu/
An excise tax differs from a sales tax in that it is imposed on particular goods and services. Excise taxes are usually unit taxes, meaning that a certain amount is collected per unit, but they can also be ad valorem taxes, meaning that the tax is a percentage of the sales price. The state excise taxes on cigarettes (ranging from 5 cents to $2.46 per pack) and liquor (ranging from $1.50 to $12.80 per gallon)6 are unit taxes. These taxes are sometimes called “sin taxes” because they are usually imposed on goods that some consider immoral or unhealthy. The reasons behind these taxes may also have to do with the desire to minimize the hissing to which Colbert referred: It’s harder for the “goose” to complain about taxes on products that can be deadly, and the relatively inelastic demands for addictive substances result in a smaller consumer response to the taxes. Sin taxes are often regressive because relatively poor people spend a larger proportion of their incomes (not to be confused with spending more in absolute terms) on consumer goods, including cigarettes and alcohol. Conversely, some excise taxes are applied to the indulgences of the rich, such as yachts and large homes, and these “luxury taxes” are clearly progressive.
6 See http:/
131
Value-
A poll tax is a type of lump-
A property tax is levied on some measure of the value of property, such as a home, an automobile, land, or an inheritance. For simplicity, the value of homes has previously been measured according to the number of windows, and, as one would expect, people responded by bricking up windows in old homes and installing fewer windows in new ones. Property taxes are generally progressive because people with high incomes are more likely than lower-
A capital gains tax is levied on profits from the sale of an asset, such as a home or shares of a stock. Capital gains on assets held for less than a year (for example, that Coca-
Participation in the popular sport of tax bashing is good fun, but when it comes time to fine-
132
From your perspective, what are the best and worst aspects of taxation?
What would life be like in the absence of taxes to pool funds for group purchases? What would you drive on after leaving your driveway? Would everyone pay to have household trash hauled to an appropriate place? Who would police toxic emissions from factories and motor vehicles? What else would be different?
If you controlled the budget in your state and had to reduce tax revenues by $10 million, what specific expenditures would you eliminate to keep the budget in balance?
Characterize the following types of taxes as progressive, regressive, or proportional:
taxes in ancient China that required 20 percent of each farmer’s crops
a roughly $130 per car tax similar to the one Governor Schwarzenegger eliminated in California (assuming for simplicity that the same amount was collected for each car)
a 10 percent tax on all income, with an exemption for the first $1,000 earned
Draw a diagram with an upward-
Repeat question 5 for open-