Suppose that Yves and Zoe are neighboring farmers, both of whom grow organic tomatoes. Both sell their output to the same grocery store chains that carry organic foods; so, in a real sense, Yves and Zoe compete with each other.
Does this mean that Yves should try to stop Zoe from growing tomatoes or that Yves and Zoe should form an agreement to grow fewer tomatoes? Almost certainly not: there are hundreds or thousands of organic tomato farmers (let’s not forget Jennifer and Jason from Module 53!), and Yves and Zoe are competing with all those other growers as well as with each other. Because so many farmers sell organic tomatoes, if any one of them produced more or fewer, there would be no measurable effect on market prices.
When people talk about business competition, they often imagine a situation in which two or three rival firms are struggling for advantage. But economists know that when a business focuses on a few main competitors, it’s actually a sign that competition is fairly limited. As the example of organic tomatoes suggests, when the number of competitors is large, it doesn’t even make sense to identify rivals and engage in aggressive competition because each firm is too small within the scope of the market to make a significant difference.
A price-
A price-
We can put it another way: Yves and Zoe are price-
A perfectly competitive market is a market in which all market participants are price-
In a perfectly competitive market, all market participants, both consumers and producers, are price-
The supply and demand model is a model of a perfectly competitive market. It depends fundamentally on the assumption that no individual buyer or seller of a good, such as coffee beans or organic tomatoes, believes that it is possible to individually affect the price at which he or she can buy or sell the good. For a firm, being a price-
A perfectly competitive industry is an industry in which firms are price-
As a general rule, consumers are indeed price-
Under what circumstances will all firms be price-
The markets for major grains, such as wheat and corn, are perfectly competitive: individual wheat and corn farmers, as well as individual buyers of wheat and corn, take market prices as given. In contrast, the markets for some of the food items made from these grains—
A firm’s market share is the fraction of the total industry output accounted for by that firm’s output.
First, for an industry to be perfectly competitive, it must contain many firms, none of whom have a large market share. A firm’s market share is the fraction of the total industry output accounted for by that firm’s output. The distribution of market share constitutes a major difference between the grain industry and the breakfast cereal industry. There are thousands of wheat farmers, none of whom account for more than a tiny fraction of total wheat sales. The breakfast cereal industry, however, is dominated by four firms: Kellogg’s, General Mills, Post, and Quaker Foods. Kellogg’s alone accounts for about one-
A good is a standardized product, also known as a commodity, when consumers regard the products of different firms as the same good.
Second, an industry can be perfectly competitive only if consumers regard the products of all firms as equivalent. This clearly isn’t true in the breakfast cereal market: consumers don’t consider Cap’n Crunch to be a good substitute for Wheaties. As a result, the maker of Wheaties has some ability to increase its price without fear that it will lose all its customers to the maker of Cap’n Crunch. Contrast this with the case of a standardized product, sometimes known as a commodity, which is a product that consumers regard as the same good even when it comes from different firms. Because wheat is a standardized product, consumers regard the output of one wheat producer as a perfect substitute for that of another producer. This means that one farmer cannot increase the price for his or her wheat without losing all sales to other wheat farmers. So the second necessary condition for a perfectly competitive industry is that the industry output is a standardized product. (See the FYI that follows.)
Interest Rates and the U.S. Housing Boom
A perfectly competitive industry must produce a standardized product. Is it enough for the products of different firms to actually be the same? No: people must also think that they are the same. Many producers go to great lengths to convince consumers that they have a distinctive, or differentiated, product, even when they don’t.
For example, consider champagne—
Similarly, Korean producers of kimchi, the spicy fermented cabbage that is the Korean national side dish, are doing their best to convince consumers that the same product packaged by Japanese firms is just not the real thing. The purpose, of course, is to ensure higher prices for Korean kimchi.
So is an industry perfectly competitive if it sells products that are indistinguishable except in name but that consumers, for whatever reason, don’t think are standardized? No. When it comes to defining the nature of competition, the consumer is always right.
An industry has free entry and exit when new firms can easily enter into the industry and existing firms can easily leave the industry.
All perfectly competitive industries have many firms with small market shares, producing a standardized product. Most perfectly competitive industries are also characterized by one more feature: it is easy for new firms to enter the industry or for firms that are currently in the industry to leave. That is, no obstacles in the form of government regulations or limited access to key resources prevent new firms from entering the market. And no additional costs are associated with shutting down a company and leaving the industry. Economists refer to the arrival of new firms into an industry as entry; they refer to the departure of firms from an industry as exit. When there are no obstacles to entry into or exit from an industry, we say that the industry has free entry and exit.
Free entry and exit is not strictly necessary for perfect competition. However, it ensures that the number of firms in an industry can adjust to changing market conditions. And, in particular, it ensures that firms in an industry cannot act to keep other firms out.
A perfectly competitive firm has a very small market share because it is easy for competing firms to enter into the industry.
To sum up, then, perfect competition depends on two necessary conditions. First, the industry must contain many firms, each having a small market share. Second, the industry must produce a standardized product. In addition, perfectly competitive industries are normally characterized by free entry and exit.