13.2 Fiscal Policy and the Multiplier

An expansionary fiscal policy, like the 2009 Economic Action Plan, pushes the aggregate demand curve to the right. A contractionary fiscal policy, like Minister of Finance Paul Martin’s 1995 federal spending cuts under Prime Minister Jean Chrétien, pushes the aggregate demand curve to the left. For policy-makers, however, knowing the direction of the shift isn’t enough: they need estimates of how much a given policy will shift the aggregate demand curve. To get these estimates, they use the concept of the multiplier, which we learned about in Chapter 11.

Multiplier Effects of an Increase in Government Purchases of Goods and Services

Suppose that a government decides to spend $50 billion building bridges and roads. The government’s purchases of goods and services will directly increase total spending on final goods and services by $50 billion. But as we learned in Chapter 11, there will also be an indirect effect: the government’s purchases will start a chain reaction throughout the economy. The firms that produce the goods and services purchased by the government earn revenues that flow to households in the form of wages, profits, interest, and rent. This increase in disposable income leads to a rise in consumer spending. The rise in consumer spending, in turn, induces firms to increase output, leading to a further rise in disposable income, which leads to another round of consumer spending increases, and so on.

As we know, the multiplier is the ratio of the change in real GDP caused by an autonomous change in aggregate expenditure to the size of that autonomous change. An increase in government purchases of goods and services is a prime example of such an autonomous increase in aggregate expenditure.

In Chapter 11 we considered a simple case in which there are no taxes or international trade, so that any change in GDP accrues entirely to households. We also assumed that the aggregate price level is fixed, so that any increase in nominal GDP is also a rise in real GDP, and that the interest rate is fixed. In that case the multiplier is 1/(1 − MPC). Recall that MPC is the marginal propensity to consume, the fraction of an additional dollar in disposable income that is spent. For example, if the marginal propensity to consume is 0.5, the multiplier is 1/(1−0.5) = 1/0.5 = 2. Given a multiplier of 2, a $50 billion increase in government purchases of goods and services would increase real GDP by $100 billion. Of that $100 billion, $50 billion is the initial effect from the increase in G, and the remaining $50 billion is the subsequent effect arising from the increase in consumer spending.3

What happens if government purchases of goods and services are instead reduced? The math is exactly the same, except that there’s a minus sign in front: if government purchases of goods and services fall by $50 billion and the marginal propensity to consume is 0.5, real GDP falls by $100 billion.

Multiplier Effects of Changes in Government Transfers and Taxes

Expansionary or contractionary fiscal policy need not take the form of changes in government purchases of goods and services. Governments can also change transfer payments or taxes. In general, however, a change in government transfers or taxes shifts the aggregate demand curve by less than an equal-sized change in government purchases, resulting in a smaller effect on real GDP.

To see why, imagine that instead of spending $50 billion on building bridges, the government simply hands out $50 billion in the form of government transfers. In this case, there is no direct effect on aggregate demand, as there was with government purchases of goods and services. Real GDP goes up only because households spend some of that $50 billion—and they probably won’t spend it all.

Table 13-1 shows a hypothetical comparison of two expansionary fiscal policies assuming an MPC equal to 0.5 and a multiplier equal to 2: one in which the government directly purchases $50 billion in goods and services and one in which the government makes transfer payments instead, sending out $50 billion in cheques to consumers. In each case there is a first-round effect on real GDP, either from purchases by the government or from purchases by the consumers who received the cheques, followed by a series of additional rounds as rising real GDP raises disposable income.

TABLE13-1: Hypothetical Effects of a Fiscal Policy with Marginal Propensity (MPC) of 0.5

However, the first-round effect of the transfer program is smaller; because we have assumed that the MPC is 0.5, only $25 billion of the $50 billion is spent, with the other $25 billion saved. And as a result, all the further rounds are smaller, too. In the end, the transfer payment increases real GDP by only $50 billion. In comparison, a $50 billion increase in government purchases produces a $100 billion increase in real GDP.

Overall, when expansionary fiscal policy takes the form of a rise in transfer payments, real GDP may rise by either more or less than the initial government outlay—that is, the multiplier may be either more or less than 1 depending upon the size of the MPC. In Table 13-1, with an MPC equal to 0.5, the multiplier is exactly 1: a $50 billion rise in transfer payments increases real GDP by $50 billion. If the MPC is less than 0.5, so that a smaller share of the initial transfer is spent, the multiplier on that transfer is less than 1. If a larger share of the initial transfer is spent, the multiplier is more than 1.

A tax cut has an effect similar to the effect of a transfer. It increases disposable income, leading to a series of increases in consumer spending. But the overall effect is smaller than that of an equal-sized increase in government purchases of goods and services: the autonomous increase in aggregate expenditure is smaller because households save part of the amount of the tax cut.

Lump-sum taxes are taxes that don’t depend on the taxpayer’s income.

We should also note that taxes introduce a further complication—they typically change the size of the multiplier. That’s because in the real world governments rarely impose lump-sum taxes, in which the amount of tax a household owes is independent of its income. With lump-sum taxes there is no change in the multiplier. Instead, the great majority of tax revenue is raised via taxes that are not lump-sum, and so tax revenue depends upon the level of real GDP. As we’ll discuss shortly, and analyze in detail in Appendix 13A, non-lump-sum taxes reduce the size of the multiplier.

In practice, economists often argue that the size of the multiplier determines who among the population should get tax cuts or increases in government transfers. For example, compare the effects of an increase in employment insurance benefits with a cut in taxes on profits distributed to shareholders as dividends. Consumer surveys suggest that the average unemployed worker will spend a higher share of any increase in his or her disposable income than would the average recipient of dividend income. That is, people who are unemployed tend to have a higher MPC than people who own a lot of stocks because the latter tend to be wealthier and tend to save more of any increase in disposable income. If that’s true, a dollar spent on employment insurance benefits increases aggregate demand more than a dollar’s worth of dividend tax cuts.

How Taxes Affect the Multiplier

When we introduced the analysis of the multiplier in Chapter 11, we simplified matters by assuming that a $1 increase in real GDP raises disposable income by $1. In fact, however, government taxes capture some part of the increase in real GDP that occurs in each round of the multiplier process, since most government taxes depend positively on real GDP. As a result, disposable income increases by considerably less than $1 once we include non-lump-sum taxes in the model.

The increase in government tax revenue when real GDP rises isn’t the result of a deliberate decision or action by the government. It’s a consequence of the way the tax laws are written, which causes most sources of government revenue to increase automatically when real GDP goes up. For example, income tax receipts increase when real GDP rises because the amount each individual owes in taxes depends positively on his or her income, and households’ taxable income rises when real GDP rises. Sales tax receipts increase when real GDP rises because people with more income spend more on goods and services. And corporate profit tax receipts increase when real GDP rises because profits increase when the economy expands.

The effect of these automatic increases in tax revenue is to reduce the size of the multiplier. Remember, the multiplier is the result of a chain reaction in which higher real GDP leads to higher disposable income, which leads to higher consumer spending, which leads to further increases in real GDP. The fact that the government siphons off some of any increase in real GDP means that at each stage of this process, the increase in consumer spending is smaller than it would be if non-lump-sum taxes weren’t part of the picture. The result is to reduce the multiplier. Appendix 13A shows how to derive the multiplier when taxes that depend positively on real GDP are taken into account.

Many macroeconomists believe it’s a good thing that in real life taxes reduce the multiplier. In Chapter 12 we argued that most, though not all, recessions are the result of negative demand shocks. The same mechanism that causes tax revenue to increase when the economy expands causes it to decrease when the economy contracts. Since tax receipts decrease when real GDP falls, the effects of these negative demand shocks are smaller than they would be if there were no taxes. The decrease in tax revenue reduces the adverse effect of the initial fall in aggregate demand—so that output does not fluctuate as much.

Automatic stabilizers are government spending and taxation rules that cause fiscal policy to be automatically expansionary when the economy contracts and automatically contractionary when the economy expands.

The automatic decrease in government tax revenue generated by a fall in real GDP—caused by a decrease in the amount of taxes households pay—acts like an automatic expansionary fiscal policy implemented in the face of contractions and recessions. Similarly, when the economy expands, the government finds itself automatically pursuing a contractionary fiscal policy—a tax increase. Government spending and taxation rules that cause fiscal policy to be automatically expansionary when the economy contracts and automatically contractionary when the economy expands, without requiring any deliberate action by policy-makers, are called automatic stabilizers.

The rules that govern tax collection aren’t the only automatic stabilizers, although they are the most important ones. Some types of government transfers also play a stabilizing role. For example, more people receive employment insurance (EI) payments when the economy is depressed than when it is booming. The same is true of social assistance programs such as welfare, rent and daycare subsidies, and student assistance grants and loans. So transfer payments tend to rise when the economy is contracting and fall when the economy is expanding. Like changes in tax revenue, these automatic changes in transfers tend to reduce the size of the multiplier because the total change in disposable income that results from a given rise or fall in real GDP is smaller.

As in the case of government tax revenue, many macroeconomists believe that it’s a good thing that government transfers reduce the multiplier. Expansionary and contractionary fiscal policies that are the result of automatic stabilizers are widely considered helpful to macroeconomic stabilization because they blunt the extremes of the business cycle.

Discretionary fiscal policy is fiscal policy that is the result of deliberate actions by policy-makers rather than rules.

But what about fiscal policy that isn’t the result of automatic stabilizers? Discretionary fiscal policy is fiscal policy that is the direct result of deliberate actions by policy-makers rather than automatic adjustment. For example, during a recession, the government may pass legislation that cuts taxes and increases government spending in order to stimulate the economy. In general, economists tend to support the use of discretionary fiscal policy only in special circumstances, such as an especially severe recession. We’ll explain why, and describe the debates among macroeconomists on the appropriate role of fiscal policy, in Chapter 18.

Prime Minister Stephen Harper and Saskatchewan Premier Brad Wall in 2009 as they announce funding to twin Highway 11 from Saskatoon to Prince Albert. The federal government paid for nearly half of the $127-million project.

MULTIPLIERS AND THE 2009 ECONOMIC ACTION PLAN

Canada’s Economic Action Plan was the largest peacetime example of discretionary fiscal expansion in Canadian history. The total stimulus was about $62 billion, including all provincial and municipal contributions. But it wasn’t spent all at once: only about half, or roughly $29 billion, of the stimulus arrived in 2009, the year of peak impact. Still, even that was a lot—roughly 1.9% of GDP.

The plan was released late in January 2009 and had three guiding principles. It was to be

  • timely, to help support the economy within the first 120 days when private demand was weakest;

  • targeted to Canadian businesses and families most in need so as to create the largest increase in Canadian jobs and output; and

  • temporary, so that the stimulus would be phased out by the time the economy recovered, thus avoiding long-term deficits and/or overstimulating the economy.

Initial government estimates of the economic impact of the proposed plan were generated using the Department of Finance’s Canadian Economic and Fiscal Model (CEFM), a complex computer-based economic–statistical model of the Canadian economy. The Model estimated that the stimulus plan would create an estimated 220 000 jobs by the end of 2010. But was that enough? From the beginning, there were some doubts.

By May 2009, Parliamentary Budget Officer (PBO) Kevin Page had begun to question the government’s estimates as to the size and timing of the multipliers. He noted that in reality the multipliers varied, sometimes dramatically, across the various kinds of tax and spending options available. The PBO provided this table of estimated multipliers:

Notice that measures aimed at households and businesses generally have multiplier effects of 1.0 or less. This occurs since these measures are subject to a greater degree of “leakage.” That is, some of the change becomes a change in savings or in imports rather than a change in demand for domestically produced output. One notable exception is a measure aimed at low-income households, which has the highest estimated multiplier; every additional dollar put into the hands of these households is thought to result in an increase in equilibrium domestic output of $1.70. This is because low-income households are more likely to spend additional funds right away, on urgent necessities such as food and clothing, rather than save the funds. Also, low-income households are more likely to spend new funds on domestic goods and services. In contrast, high-income households are more likely to save the money from a tax cut or to spend it on imported items.

Minister of Finance Jim Flaherty presents details of Canada’s Economic Action Plan.

Other reservations were expressed, too. About three times more of the plan’s measures focused on areas with multipliers exceeding 1.0 than those with smaller multipliers. The fact that about one quarter of the stimulus spending was on measures with “small” multipliers led the PBO and others to question whether those most in need were truly being assisted. Critics, including the PBO, also questioned whether the plan could be “rolled out” on a timely basis. They noted that while housing investment and infrastructure projects do have high multiplier effects, these projects tend to start very slowly. Further, the government, hoping to have the plan rolled out within a two-year “window,” demanded that the EAP money be spent on “shovel-ready” projects. Many wondered whether enough such projects existed to meet this requirement. If such projects could not be found or encountered delays, then the timeliness and size of stimulus delivered would be reduced.

However, despite the reservations people had about the Plan, it seems to have succeeded. In February 2010, just over a year after the Plan was proposed, the Conference Board of Canada stated that these forecasts and their associated estimated impact on the economy were reasonable and conservative. That is, the assumed or estimated multiplier effects were not too aggressive and thus the estimated stimulus was not being overstated for the intended two-year plan window. And if the Plan had not been introduced, it is likely that Canada would have experienced a far worse recession in 2009 than it did. Total employment did rise by more than 300 000 from January 2009 to January 2011, primarily in Ontario and Quebec. However, there is no way to determine what percentage of this increase was the result of the Plan itself. In fact, about 90 000 more Canadians were classified as unemployed in January 2011 than in January 2009, because as the economy improved, more people joined the labour force to seek work.

Quick Review

  • The amount by which changes in government purchases raise real GDP is determined by the multiplier.

  • Changes in taxes and government transfers also move real GDP, but by less than equal-sized changes in government purchases.

  • Taxes reduce the size of the multiplier unless they are lump-sum taxes.

  • Taxes and some government transfers act as automatic stabilizers as tax revenue is positively correlated (that is, moves in the same direction) with changes in real GDP and some government transfers are negatively correlated with changes in real GDP. Many economists believe that it is a good thing that they reduce the size of the multiplier. In contrast, the use of discretionary fiscal policy is more controversial.

Check Your Understanding 13-2

CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING 13-2

Question 13.4

Explain why a $500 million increase in government purchases of goods and services will generate a larger rise in real GDP than a $500 million increase in government transfers.

A $500 million increase in government purchases of goods and services directly increases aggregate expenditure by $500 million, which then starts the multiplier in motion. It will increase real GDP by $500 million × 1/(1 – MPC). A $500 million increase in government transfers increases aggregate expenditure only to the extent that it leads to an increase in consumer spending. Consumer spending rises by MPC × $1 for every $1 increase in disposable income, where MPC is less than 1. So a $500 million increase in government transfers will cause a rise in real GDP only MPC times as much as a $500 million increase in government purchases of goods and services. It will increase real GDP by $500 million × MPC/(1 – MPC).

Question 13.5

Explain why a $500 million reduction in government purchases of goods and services will generate a larger fall in real GDP than a $500 million reduction in government transfers.

This is the same issue as in Problem 1, but in reverse. If government purchases of goods and services fall by $500 million, the initial fall in aggregate expenditure is $500 million. If there is a $500 million reduction in government transfers, the initial fall in aggregate expenditure is MPC × $500 million, which is less than $500 million.

Question 13.6

The country of Boldovia has no employment insurance benefits and a tax system using only lump-sum taxes. The neighbouring country of Moldovia has generous employment benefits and a tax system in which residents must pay a percentage of their income. Which country will experience greater variation in real GDP in response to demand shocks, positive and negative? Explain.

Boldovia will experience greater variation in its real GDP than Moldovia because Moldovia has automatic stabilizers while Boldovia does not. In Moldovia the effects of slumps will be lessened by unemployment insurance benefits that will support residents’ incomes, while the effects of booms will be diminished because tax revenues will go up. In contrast, incomes will not be supported in Boldovia during slumps because there is no unemployment insurance. In addition, because Boldovia has lump-sum taxes, its booms will not be diminished by increases in tax revenue.