18.2 The Great Depression and the Keynesian Revolution

The Great Depression demonstrated, once and for all, that economists cannot safely ignore the short run. Not only was the economic pain severe; it threatened to destabilize societies and political systems. In particular, the economic plunge helped Adolf Hitler rise to power in Germany.

The whole world wanted to know how this economic disaster could be happening and what should be done about it. But because there was no widely accepted theory of the business cycle, economists gave conflicting and, we now believe, often harmful advice. Some believed that only a huge change in the economic system—such as having the government take over much of private industry and replace markets with a command economy—could end the slump. Others argued that slumps were natural—even beneficial—and that nothing should be done.

Some economists, however, argued that the slump both could and should be cured—without giving up on the basic idea of a market economy. In 1930 the British economist John Maynard Keynes compared the problems of the U.S. and British economies to those of a car with a defective starter. Getting the economy running, he argued, would require only a modest repair, not a complete overhaul.

Nice metaphor. But what was the nature of the trouble?

Keynes’s Theory

In 1936 Keynes presented his analysis of the Great Depression—his explanation of what was wrong with the economy’s starter—in a book titled The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. In 1946 the great American economist Paul Samuelson wrote that “it is a badly written book, poorly organized …. Flashes of insight and intuition intersperse tedious algebra …. We find its analysis to be obvious and at the same time new. In short, it is a work of genius.” The General Theory isn’t easy reading, but it stands with Adam Smith’s The Wealth of Nations as one of the most influential books on economics ever written.

As Samuelson’s description suggests, Keynes’s book is a vast stew of ideas. Keynesian economics is principally based on two innovations. First, Keynes emphasized the short-run effects of changes in aggregate demand on aggregate output, rather than the long-run determination of the aggregate price level. As Keynes’s famous remark about being dead in the long run suggests, until his book appeared most economists had treated short-run macroeconomics as a minor issue. Keynes focused the attention of economists on situations in which the short-run aggregate supply curve slopes upward and shifts in the aggregate demand curve affect aggregate output and employment as well as aggregate prices.

Figure 18-2 illustrates the difference between Keynesian and classical macroeconomics. Both panels of the figure show the short-run aggregate supply curve, SRAS; in both it is assumed that for some reason the aggregate demand curve shifts leftward from AD1 to AD2—let’s say in response to a fall in stock market prices that leads households to reduce consumer spending.

Figure18-2Classical versus Keynesian Macroeconomics One important difference between classical and Keynesian economics involves the short-run aggregate supply curve. Panel (a) shows the classical view: the SRAS curve is vertical, so shifts in aggregate demand affect the aggregate price level but not aggregate output. Panel (b) shows the Keynesian view: in the short run the SRAS curve slopes upward, so shifts in aggregate demand affect aggregate output as well as aggregate prices.

Panel (a) shows the classical view: the short-run aggregate supply curve is vertical. The decline in aggregate demand leads to a fall in the aggregate price level, from P1 to P2, but no change in aggregate output. Panel (b) shows the Keynesian view: the short-run aggregate supply curve slopes upward, so the decline in aggregate demand leads to both a fall in the aggregate price level, from P1 to P2, and a fall in aggregate output, from Y1 to Y2.

As we’ve already explained, many classical macroeconomists would have agreed that panel (b) was an accurate story in the short run—but they regarded the short run as unimportant. Keynes disagreed. [Just to be clear, there isn’t any diagram that looks like panel (b) of Figure 18-2 in Keynes’s General Theory. But Keynes’s discussion of aggregate supply, translated into modern terminology, clearly implies an upward-sloping SRAS curve.]

Classical economists emphasized the role of changes in the money supply in shifting the aggregate demand curve, paying little attention to other factors. Keynes’s second innovation was his argument that other factors, especially changes in “animal spirits”—these days usually referred to with the bland term business confidence—are mainly responsible for business cycles. Before Keynes, economists often argued that a decline in business confidence would have no effect on either the aggregate price level or aggregate output, as long as the money supply stayed constant. Keynes offered a very different picture.

Keynesian economics rests on two main tenets: changes in aggregate demand affect aggregate output, employment, and prices; and changes in business confidence cause the business cycle.

Keynesian economics has penetrated deeply into the public consciousness, to the extent that many people who have never heard of Keynes, or have heard of him but think they disagree with his theory, use Keynesian ideas all the time. For example, suppose that a business commentator says something like this: “Because of a decline in business confidence, investment spending slumped, causing a recession.” Whether the commentator knows it or not, that statement is pure Keynesian economics.

THE POLITICS OF KEYNES

Some people consider Keynesian economics a synonym for left-wing economics. But this is misguided because in reality the ideas of John Maynard Keynes have been accepted across a broad sweep of the political spectrum.

The term Keynesian economics is sometimes used as a synonym for left-wing economics: authors seem to believe that because Keynes offered a rationale for some kinds of government activism, he was a leftist of some kind, maybe even a socialist. But the truth is more complicated.

As we explain in the text, Keynesian ideas have actually been accepted across a broad range of the political spectrum. In 2004 the American president was a conservative, as was his top economist, N. Gregory Mankiw; but Mankiw is also the editor of a collection of readings titled New Keynesian Economics.

And Keynes himself was no socialist—and not much of a leftist. At the time The General Theory was published, many intellectuals in Britain believed that the Great Depression was the final crisis of the capitalist economic system and that only a government takeover of industry could save the economy. Keynes, in contrast, argued that all the system needed was a narrow technical fix. In that sense, his ideas were pro-capitalist and politically conservative.

What is true is that the rise of Keynesian economics in the 1940s, 1950s, and 1960s went along with a general enlargement of the role of government in the economy, and those who favoured a larger role for government tended to be enthusiastic Keynesians. Conversely, a swing of the pendulum back toward free-market policies in the 1970s and 1980s was accompanied by a series of challenges to Keynesian ideas, which we describe later in this chapter. But it’s perfectly possible to have conservative political preferences while respecting Keynes’s contribution and equally possible to be very liberal while questioning Keynes’s ideas.

Keynes himself more or less predicted that his ideas would become part of what “everyone knows.” In another famous passage, this from the end of The General Theory, he wrote: “Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influences, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist.”

Policy to Fight Recessions

Macroeconomic policy activism is the use of monetary and fiscal policy to smooth out the business cycle.

The main practical consequence of Keynes’s work was that it legitimized macroeconomic policy activism—the use of monetary and fiscal policy to smooth out the business cycle.

Macroeconomic policy activism wasn’t something completely new. Before Keynes, many economists had argued for using monetary expansion to fight economic downturns—though others were fiercely opposed. Some economists had even argued that temporary budget deficits were a good thing in times of recession—though others disagreed strongly. In practice, during the 1930s many governments followed policies that we would now call Keynesian. In Canada, the Bennett government provided some welfare programs to fight the depression, which made the federal government run larger budget deficits.

However, these efforts were half-hearted. Worried about its budget deficit, the Bennett government began to cut spending in 1932. Given that the economy was still depressed, these spending cuts worsened economic conditions.

After World War II, Keynesian ideas were broadly accepted by economists. There were, however, a series of challenges to those ideas, which led to a considerable shift in views even among those economists who continued to believe that Keynes was broadly right about the causes of recessions. In the upcoming section, we’ll learn about those challenges and the schools, new classical economics and new Keynesian economics, that emerged.

THE END OF THE GREAT DEPRESSION

It would make a good story if Keynes’s ideas had led to a change in economic policy that brought the Great Depression to an end. Unfortunately, that’s not what happened. Still, the way the Depression ended did a lot to convince economists that Keynes was right.

The basic message many of the young economists who adopted Keynes’s ideas in the 1930s took from his work was that economic recovery requires aggressive fiscal expansion—deficit spending on a large scale to create jobs. And that is what they eventually got; but it wasn’t because politicians were persuaded. Instead, what happened was a very large war, World War II.

Figure 18-3 shows the Canadian unemployment rate and the federal budget deficit as a percentage of GDP from 1930 to 1950. As you can see, during the 1930s, deficit spending occurred on a very modest scale. It was only after Canada entered World War II in 1939 that federal deficit spending really began to increase—eventually reaching truly mammoth proportions (23% of GDP) by 1943.2

Figure18-3Fiscal Policy and the End of the Great Depression Source: Historical Statistics Of Canada.

And the economy recovered. World War II wasn’t intended as a Keynesian fiscal policy, but it demonstrated that expansionary fiscal policy can, in fact, create jobs in the short run.

Quick Review

  • The key innovations of Keynesian economics are an emphasis on the short run, in which the SRAS curve slopes upward rather than being vertical, and the belief that changes in business confidence shift the AD curve and thereby generate business cycles.

  • Keynesian economics provided a rationale for macroeconomic policy activism.

  • Keynesian ideas are widely used even by people who haven’t heard of Keynes or think they disagree with him.

Check Your Understanding 18-2

CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING 18-2

Question 18.2

The Canadian Federation of Independent Business (CFIB) calculates an index of business confidence known as the Business Barometer. In February 2013, the CFIB stated, “After a lacklustre November and December, Canadian entrepreneurs are feeling more optimistic in early 2013 … The Business Barometer index continued January’s upward trend by rising another half a point to 66.2 in February.” Ted Mallett, CFIB’s chief economist and vice-president reported, “For the first time in a while, small business owners are reporting index numbers that indicate the economy is growing nearer its potential. The January and February results suggest Canadians are seeing modest, but widespread economic growth.” Do these statements support Keynesian theory? Which conclusion would a Keynesian economist draw for the need for public policy?

The statements support Keynesian theory. According to Keynes, business confidence (which he called “animal spirits”) is mainly responsible for recessions. If business confidence is rising, a Keynesian economist would think that investment would rise and aggregate demand would shift to the right. As the economy is recovering from a recession, a Keynesian economist would think of this as a case for macroeconomic policy activism: that the government should use expansionary monetary and fiscal policy to help the economy reaches its potential output faster (i.e., to speed up the recovery).