The 1970s and the first half of the 1980s were a stormy period for the Canadian economy (and for other major economies, too). There were several slowdowns in output that threatened to push the economy into recession, especially in 1975 and again in 1980, followed by a severe recession in 1982–1983 that sent the annual unemployment rate to 12% in 1983. At the same time, the inflation rate soared into double digits—
The Great Moderation is the period from 1992 to 2007 when the Canadian economy experienced relatively small fluctuations and low inflation.
After about 1991, however, the economy settled down. The recession of 1990–1991 was much milder than the 1982–1983 recession, and the inflation rate stayed below 3%. The period of relative calm in the economy from 1992 to 2007 came to be known as the Great Moderation.4 And the calmness of the economy was to a large extent marked by a similar calm in macroeconomic policy discussion. In fact, it seemed that a broad consensus had emerged about several key macroeconomic issues.
The Great Moderation consensus combines a belief in monetary policy as the main tool of stabilization, with skepticism toward the use of fiscal policy, and an acknowledgement that monetary policy generally only has short-
The Great Moderation was, unfortunately, followed by the Great Recession, the severe and persistent slump that followed the worldwide 2008 financial crisis. We’ll talk shortly about the policy disputes caused by the Great Recession. First, however, let’s examine the apparent consensus that emerged during the Great Moderation, which we call the Great Moderation consensus. It combines a belief in monetary policy as the main tool of stabilization, with skepticism toward the use of fiscal policy, and an acknowledgement of the policy constraints imposed by the natural rate of unemployment and the political business cycle. To understand where it came from and what still remains in dispute, we’ll look at how macroeconomists have changed their answers to five key questions about macroeconomic policy. The five questions and the various answers given by schools of macroeconomics over the decades are summarized in Table 18-1. (In the table, new classical economics is subsumed under classical economics, and new Keynesian economics is subsumed under the Great Moderation consensus.) Notice that classical macroeconomics said no to each question; basically, classical macroeconomists didn’t think macroeconomic policy could accomplish very much. But let’s go through the questions one by one.
As we’ve seen, classical macroeconomists generally believed that expansionary monetary policy was ineffective or even harmful in fighting recessions. In the early years of Keynesian economics, macroeconomists weren’t against monetary expansion during recessions, but they tended to believe that it was of doubtful effectiveness. Milton Friedman and his monetarist followers convinced economists that monetary policy is effective after all.
Nearly all macroeconomists now agree that monetary policy can be used to shift the aggregate demand curve and to reduce economic instability. The classical view that changes in the money supply affect only aggregate prices, not aggregate output, has few supporters today. The view held by early Keynesian economists—
Classical macroeconomists were, if anything, even more opposed to fiscal expansion than monetary expansion. Keynesian economists, on the other hand, gave fiscal policy a central role in fighting recessions. Monetarists argued that fiscal policy was ineffective if the money supply was held constant. But that strong view has become relatively rare.
Most macroeconomists now agree that fiscal policy, like monetary policy, can shift the aggregate demand curve. Most macroeconomists also agree that the government should not seek to balance the budget regardless of the state of the economy: they agree that the role of the budget as an automatic stabilizer helps keep the economy on an even keel.
Classical macroeconomists didn’t believe the government could do anything about unemployment. Some Keynesian economists moved to the opposite extreme, arguing that expansionary policies could be used to achieve a permanently low unemployment rate, perhaps at the cost of some inflation. Monetarists believed that unemployment could not be kept below the natural rate.
Almost all macroeconomists now accept the natural rate hypothesis. This hypothesis leads them to accept sharp limits to what monetary and fiscal policy can accomplish. Effective monetary and fiscal policy, most macroeconomists believe, can limit the size of fluctuations of the actual unemployment rate around the natural rate, but they can’t be used to continually keep unemployment below the natural rate in the longer term.
As we’ve already seen, views about the effectiveness of fiscal policy have gone back and forth, from rejection by classical macroeconomists, to a positive view by Keynesian economists, to a negative view once again by monetarists. Today most macroeconomists believe that tax cuts and spending increases are at least somewhat effective in increasing aggregate demand.
Many, but not all, macroeconomists, however, believe that discretionary fiscal policy is usually counterproductive, for the reasons discussed in Chapter 13: the lags in adjusting fiscal policy mean that, all too often, policies intended to fight a slump end up intensifying a boom.
As a result, the macroeconomic consensus gives monetary policy the lead role in economic stabilization. Some, but not all, economists believe that fiscal policy must be brought back into the mix under special circumstances, in particular when interest rates are at or near the zero lower bound and the economy is in a liquidity trap. As we’ll see shortly, the proper role of fiscal policy became a huge point of contention after 2008.
Classical macroeconomists didn’t think that monetary policy should be used to fight recessions; Keynesian economists didn’t oppose discretionary monetary policy, but they were skeptical about its effectiveness. Monetarists argued that discretionary monetary policy was doing more harm than good. Where are we today? This remains an area of dispute. Today, under the Great Moderation consensus, most macreconomists agree on these three points:
Monetary policy should play the main role in stabilization policy.
The central bank should be independent, insulated from political pressures, in order to avoid a political business cycle and/or a bias to create unexpected bouts of inflation so as to lower the real cost of past government borrowing (debt).
Discretionary fiscal policy should be used sparingly, both because of policy lags and because of the risks of a political business cycle.
However, the Great Moderation was upended by events that posed very difficult questions—
The Great Recession shattered any sense among macroeconomists that they had entered a permanent era of agreement over key policy questions. Given the nature of the slump, however, this should not have come as a surprise. Why? Because the severity of the slump arguably made the policies that seemed to work during the Great Moderation inadequate.
Under the Great Moderation consensus, there had been broad agreement that the job of stabilizing the economy was best carried out by having the Bank of Canada and its counterparts abroad raise or lower interest rates as the economic situation warranted. But what should be done if the economy is deeply depressed, but the interest rates the Bank of Canada normally controls are already close to zero and can go no lower (that is, when the economy is in a liquidity trap)? Some economists called for the aggressive use of discretionary fiscal policy and/or unconventional monetary policies that might achieve results despite the zero lower bound. Others strongly opposed these measures, arguing either that they would be ineffective or that they would produce undesirable side effects.
The Debate over Fiscal Policy In 2009 a number of governments, including that of Canada, responded with expansionary fiscal policy, or “stimulus,” generally taking the form of a mix of temporary spending measures and temporary tax cuts. From the start, however, these efforts were highly controversial.
Supporters of fiscal stimulus offered three main arguments for breaking with the normal presumption against discretionary fiscal policy:
They argued that discretionary fiscal expansion was needed because the usual tool for stabilizing the economy, monetary policy, could no longer be used now that interest rates were near zero.
They argued that one normal concern about expansionary fiscal policy—
Finally, they argued that another concern about discretionary fiscal policy—
These arguments generally won the day in early 2009. However, opponents of fiscal stimulus raised two main objections:
They argued that households and firms would see any rise in government spending as a sign that tax burdens were likely to rise in the future, leading to a fall in private spending that would undo any positive effect. (This is the Ricardian equivalence argument that we encountered in Chapter 13.)
They also warned that spending programs might undermine investors’ faith in the government’s ability to repay its debts, leading to an increase in long-
In fact, by 2010 a number of economists were arguing that the best way to boost the economy was actually to cut government spending, which they argued would increase private-
One might have hoped that events would resolve this dispute. At the time this book went to press, however, the debate was still raging throughout the world. For instance, critics of fiscal stimulus pointed out that the U.S. stimulus had failed to deliver a convincing fall in unemployment; stimulus advocates, however, had warned from the start that this was likely to happen because the stimulus was too small compared with the depth of the slump. Meanwhile, austerity programs in Britain and elsewhere had also failed to deliver an economic turnaround and, in fact, had seemed to deepen the slump; supporters of these programs, however, argued that they were nonetheless necessary to head off a potential collapse of confidence.
One thing that was clear, however, was that those who had predicted a sharp rise in Canadian interest rates due to budget deficits, leading to conventional crowding out, had been wrong: by the fall of 2011, long-
The Debate over Monetary Policy As we saw in Chapter 16, a central bank that wants to increase aggregate demand conventionally buys short-
Beginning in 2008, a number of central banks, including the Bank of England, the Bank of Japan, the Central European Bank, and the U.S. Federal Reserve pursued one such alternative, known as “quantitative easing,” which involved buying assets other than short-
The policy of quantitative easing was controversial, facing criticisms both from those who believed that the Fed was doing too much and from those who believed it was doing too little. Those who believed that the Fed was doing too much were concerned about possible future inflation; they argued that the Fed would find its unconventional measures hard to reverse as the economy recovered and that the end result would be a much too expansionary monetary policy.
Critics from the other side argued that the Fed’s actions were likely to be ineffective: long-
Many of those calling on the Fed for even more active policy advocated an official rise in the Fed’s inflation target. Recall from Chapters 8 and 10 the distinction between the nominal interest rate, which is the number normally cited, and the real interest rate—
Such proposals, however, led to fierce disputes. Some economists pointed out that the Fed had fought hard to drive inflation expectations down and argued that changing course would undermine hard-
At the time of writing, these disputes were still raging, and it seemed unlikely that a new consensus about macroeconomic policy would emerge any time soon.
Over the course of 2010 and 2011 a fierce debate raged, among both economists and policy-
How could this dispute be settled? Researchers turned their attention to historical episodes, in particular to cases in which nations had managed to combine sharp reductions in budget deficits with strong economic growth. One case in particular became a major intellectual battleground: Ireland in the second half of the 1980s.
Panel (a) of Figure 18-7 shows why Ireland’s experience drew attention. It compares Ireland’s cyclically adjusted budget deficit as a percentage of GDP with its growth rate. Between 1986 and 1989 Ireland drastically reduced its underlying deficits with a combination of spending cuts and tax hikes, and the Irish economy’s growth sharply accelerated. A number of observers suggested that nations facing large deficits in the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis should seek to emulate that experience.
A closer look, however, suggested that Ireland’s situation in the 1980s was very different from that facing Western economies in 2010 and 2011. Panel (b) of Figure 18-7 shows two other economic indicators for Ireland from 1986 to 1990: short-
The point was that these “cushioning” factors would not be available if, say, Canada were to slash spending. Short-
By the end of 2011 careful study of the historical record had convinced most, though not all, economists studying the issue that hopes for expansionary austerity were probably misplaced. However, the debate about what Canada and other troubled economies should actually do raged on.
The Great Moderation, the period of relative world economic calm from 1992 to 2007, produced the Great Moderation consensus.
According to the Great Moderation consensus: monetary policy should be the main stabilization tool; to avoid a political business cycle, the central bank should be independent and fiscal policy should not be used, except possibly in exceptional circumstances such as a liquidity trap; and the natural rate of unemployment limits how much policy activism can reduce the unemployment rate.
The Great Moderation consensus was severely challenged by the Great Recession. Active fiscal policy was revived given the ineffectiveness of monetary policy in the midst of a liquidity trap. Fiercely debated, fiscal stimulus in the United States failed to deliver a significant fall in unemployment. Critics cited this as evidence that fiscal policy doesn’t work, while supporters countered that the size of the stimulus was too small. However, crowding out failed to materialize as critics had warned that it would.
Monetary policy was also deeply controversial in the wake of the Great Recession, as the U.S. Federal Reserve pursued “quantitative easing” and other unconventional policies. Critics claimed the Fed was doing too much and too little, while some advocated the adoption of a higher inflation target to push the real interest rate down.
CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING 18-5
Why did the Great Recession lead to the decline of the Great Moderation consensus? Given events, why is it predictable that a new consensus has not emerged?
The liquidity trap brought on by the Great Recession greatly diminished the Great Moderation consensus because it considered monetary policy to be the main policy tool and monetary policy was now largely ineffective. The continuing disagreements over fiscal policy were now brought to the forefront as fiscal policy was used by policy-