263
An oligopoly is an industry with only a small number of producers. A producer in such an industry is known as an oligopolist.
At the time of that elaborately bugged meeting, no one company controlled the world lysine industry, but there were only a few major producers. An industry with only a few sellers is known as an oligopoly; a firm in such an industry is known as an oligopolist.
Oligopolists obviously compete with one another for sales. But neither ADM nor Ajinomoto were like a firm in a perfectly competitive industry, which takes the price at which it can sell its product as given. In the case of ADM and Ajinomoto, each firm knew that its decision about how much to produce would affect the market price. That is, like monopolists, each of the firms had some market power. So the competition in this industry wasn’t “perfect.”
When no one firm has a monopoly, but producers nonetheless realize that they can affect market prices, an industry is characterized by imperfect competition.
Economists refer to a situation in which firms compete but also possess market power—
Although lysine is a multibillion-
It’s important to realize that an oligopoly isn’t necessarily made up of large firms. What matters isn’t size per se; the question is how many competitors there are. When a small town has only two grocery stores, grocery service there is just as much an oligopoly as air shuttle service between New York and Washington.
Why are oligopolies so prevalent? Essentially, oligopoly is the result of the same factors that sometimes produce monopoly, but in somewhat weaker form. Probably the most important source of oligopoly is the existence of increasing returns to scale, which give bigger producers a cost advantage over smaller ones. When these effects are very strong, they lead to monopoly; when they are not that strong, they lead to an industry with a small number of firms.
For example, larger grocery stores typically have lower costs than smaller ones. But the advantages of large scale taper off once grocery stores are reasonably large, which is why two or three stores often survive in small towns.
If oligopoly is so common, why has most of this book focused on competition in industries where the number of sellers is very large? And why did we study monopoly, which is relatively uncommon, first, in Chapter 8? The answer has two parts.
First, much of what we learn from the study of perfectly competitive markets—
How much will a firm produce? Up to this point, we have always answered: the quantity that maximizes its profit. Together with its cost curves, the assumption that a firm maximizes profit is enough to determine its output when it is a perfect competitor or a monopolist.
264
When it comes to oligopoly, however, we run into some difficulties. Indeed, economists often describe the behavior of oligopolistic firms as a “puzzle.”
An oligopoly consisting of only two firms is a duopoly. Each firm is known as a duopolist.
A Duopoly Example Let’s begin looking at the puzzle of oligopoly with the simplest version, an industry in which there are only two producing firms—
Going back to our opening story, imagine that ADM and Ajinomoto are the only two producers of lysine. To make things even simpler, suppose that once a company has incurred the fixed cost needed to produce lysine, the marginal cost of producing another pound is zero. So the companies are concerned only with the revenue they receive from sales.
Table 9-1 shows a hypothetical demand schedule for lysine and the total revenue of the industry at each price–quantity combination.
Price of lysine (per pound) |
Quantity of lysine demanded (millions of pounds) |
Total revenue (millions) |
$12 | 0 | $0 |
11 | 10 | 110 |
10 | 20 | 200 |
9 | 30 | 270 |
8 | 40 | 320 |
7 | 50 | 350 |
6 | 60 | 360 |
5 | 70 | 350 |
4 | 80 | 320 |
3 | 90 | 270 |
2 | 100 | 200 |
1 | 110 | 110 |
0 | 120 | 0 |
If this were a perfectly competitive industry, each firm would have an incentive to produce more as long as the market price was above marginal cost. Since the marginal cost is assumed to be zero, this would mean that at equilibrium lysine would be provided free. Firms would produce until price equals zero, yielding a total output of 120 million pounds and zero revenue for both firms.
However, surely the firms would not be that stupid. With only two firms in the industry, each would realize that by producing more, it drives down the market price. So each firm would, like a monopolist, realize that profits would be higher if it and its rival limited their production.
So how much will the two firms produce?
Sellers engage in collusion when they cooperate to raise their joint profits. A cartel is an agreement among several producers to obey output restrictions in order to increase their joint profits.
One possibility is that the two companies will engage in collusion—
As its name indicates, OPEC is actually an agreement among governments rather than firms. There’s a reason this most famous of cartels is an agreement among governments: cartels among firms are illegal in the United States and many other jurisdictions. But let’s ignore the law for a moment (which is, of course, what ADM and Ajinomoto did in real life—
So suppose that ADM and Ajinomoto were to form a cartel and that this cartel decided to act as if it were a monopolist, maximizing total industry profits. It’s obvious from Table 9-1 that in order to maximize the combined profits of the firms, this cartel should set total industry output at 60 million pounds of lysine, which would sell at a price of $6 per pound, leading to revenue of $360 million, the maximum possible.
Then the only question would be how much of that 60 million pounds each firm gets to produce. A “fair” solution might be for each firm to produce 30 million pounds with revenues for each firm of $180 million.
But even if the two firms agreed on such a deal, they might have a problem: each of the firms would have an incentive to break its word and produce more than the agreed-
Collusion and Competition Suppose that the presidents of ADM and Ajinomoto were to agree that each would produce 30 million pounds of lysine over the next year. Both would understand that this plan maximizes their combined profits. And both would have an incentive to cheat.
265
To see why, consider what would happen if Ajinomoto honored its agreement, producing only 30 million pounds, but ADM ignored its promise and produced 40 million pounds. This increase in total output would drive the price down from $6 to $5 per pound, the price at which 70 million pounds are demanded. The industry’s total revenue would fall from $360 million ($6 × 60 million pounds) to $350 million ($5 × 70 million pounds). However, ADM’s revenue would rise, from $180 million to $200 million. Since we are assuming a marginal cost of zero, this would mean a $20 million increase in ADM’s profits.
But Ajinomoto’s president might make exactly the same calculation. And if both firms were to produce 40 million pounds of lysine, the price would drop to $4 per pound. So each firm’s profits would fall, from $180 million to $160 million.
Why do individual firms have an incentive to produce more than the quantity that maximizes their joint profits? Because neither firm has as strong an incentive to limit its output as a true monopolist would.
Let’s go back for a minute to the theory of monopoly. We know that a profit-
A positive quantity effect: one more unit is sold, increasing total revenue by the price at which that unit is sold.
A negative price effect: in order to sell one more unit, the monopolist must cut the market price on all units sold.
The negative price effect is the reason marginal revenue for a monopolist is less than the market price. In the case of oligopoly, when considering the effect of increasing production, a firm is concerned only with the price effect on its own units of output, not those of its fellow oligopolists. Both ADM and Ajinomoto suffer a negative price effect if ADM decides to produce extra lysine and so drives down the price. But ADM cares only about the negative price effect on the units it produces, not about the loss to Ajinomoto.
This tells us that an individual firm in an oligopolistic industry faces a smaller price effect from an additional unit of output than does a monopolist; therefore, the marginal revenue that such a firm calculates is higher. So it will seem to be profitable for any one company in an oligopoly to increase production, even if that increase reduces the profits of the industry as a whole. But if everyone thinks that way, the result is that everyone earns a lower profit!
When firms ignore the effects of their actions on each others’ profits, they engage in noncooperative behavior.
Until now, we have been able to analyze producer behavior by asking what a producer should do to maximize profits. But even if ADM and Ajinomoto are both trying to maximize profits, what does this predict about their behavior? Will they engage in collusion, reaching and holding to an agreement that maximizes their combined profits? Or will they engage in noncooperative behavior, with each firm acting in its own self-
Now you see why oligopoly presents a puzzle: there are only a small number of players, making collusion a real possibility. If there were dozens or hundreds of firms, it would be safe to assume they would behave noncooperatively. Yet when there are only a handful of firms in an industry, it’s hard to determine whether collusion will actually materialize.
Since collusion is ultimately more profitable than noncooperative behavior, firms have an incentive to collude if they can. One way to do so is to formalize it—
266
In fact, executives from rival companies rarely meet without lawyers present, who make sure that the conversation does not stray into inappropriate territory. Even hinting at how nice it would be if prices were higher can bring you an unwelcome interview with the Justice Department or the Federal Trade Commission.
For example, in 2003 the Justice Department launched a price-
Sometimes, as we’ve seen, oligopolistic firms just ignore the rules. But more often they find ways to achieve collusion without a formal agreement, as we’ll soon see.
How oligopolies usually work in practice depends on the legal framework that limits what firms can do and on the underlying ability of firms in a given industry to cooperate without formal agreements.
The Legal Framework To understand oligopoly pricing in practice, we need to understand the legal constraints under which oligopolistic firms operate. In the United States, oligopoly first became an issue during the second half of the nineteenth century, when the growth of railroads—
Large firms producing oil, steel, and many other products soon emerged. The industrialists quickly realized that profits would be higher if they could limit price competition. So, many industries formed cartels—
However, although these cartels were legal, they weren’t legally enforceable—members of a cartel couldn’t ask the courts to force a firm that was violating its agreement to reduce its production. And firms often did violate their agreements, for the reason already suggested by our duopoly example: there is always a temptation for each firm in a cartel to produce more than it is supposed to.
In 1881 clever lawyers at John D. Rockefeller’s Standard Oil Company came up with a solution—
Antitrust policy consists of efforts undertaken by the government to prevent oligopolistic industries from becoming or behaving like monopolies.
Eventually there was a public backlash, driven partly by concern about the economic effects of the trust movement, partly by fear that the owners of the trusts were simply becoming too powerful. The result was the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890, which was intended both to prevent the creation of more monopolies and to break up existing ones. At first this law went largely unenforced. But over the decades that followed, the federal government became increasingly committed to making it difficult for oligopolistic industries either to become monopolies or to behave like them. Such efforts are known to this day as antitrust policy.
267
Among advanced countries, the United States is unique in its long tradition of antitrust policy. Until recently, other advanced countries did not have policies against price-
During the early 1990s, the United States instituted an amnesty program in which a price-
Life has gotten much tougher for those who want to operate a cartel.
Tacit Collusion and Price Wars If a real industry were as simple as our lysine example, it probably wouldn’t be necessary for the company presidents to meet or do anything that could land them in jail. Both firms would realize that it was in their mutual interest to restrict output to 30 million pounds each and that any short-
When firms limit production and raise prices in a way that raises one anothers’ profits, even though they have not made any formal agreement, they are engaged in tacit collusion.
Firms are said to be engaged in tacit collusion when, as in our example, they restrict output in a way that raises the profits of another firm, and expect the favor to be returned even without an enforceable agreement—
Real industries are nowhere near this simple. Nonetheless, in most oligopolistic industries, most of the time, the sellers do appear to succeed in keeping prices above their noncooperative level. Tacit collusion, in other words, is the normal state of oligopoly.
Although tacit collusion is common, it rarely allows an industry to push prices all the way up to their monopoly level; collusion is usually far from perfect. As we discuss next, there are four factors that make it hard for an industry to coordinate on high prices.
Less Concentration In a less concentrated industry, the typical firm will have a smaller market share than in a more concentrated industry. This tilts firms toward noncooperative behavior because when a smaller firm cheats and increases its output, it gains for itself all of the profit from the higher output. And if its rivals retaliate by increasing their output, the firm’s losses are limited because of its relatively modest market share. A less concentrated industry is often an indication that there are low barriers to entry.
Complex Products and Pricing Schemes In our lysine example the two firms produce only one product. In reality, however, oligopolists often sell thousands or even tens of thousands of different products. Under these circumstances, keeping track of what other firms are producing and the prices they are charging is difficult. This makes it hard to determine whether a firm is cheating on the tacit agreement.
Differences in Interests In the lysine example, a tacit agreement for the firms to split the market equally is a natural outcome, probably acceptable to both firms. In real industries, however, firms often differ both in their perceptions about what is fair and in their real interests.
268
For example, suppose that Ajinomoto was a long-
Alternatively, suppose that ADM’s marginal costs were lower than Ajinomoto’s. Even if they could agree on market shares, they would then disagree about the profit-
Bargaining Power of Buyers Often oligopolists sell not to individual consumers but to large buyers—
These difficulties in enforcing tacit collusion have sometimes led companies to defy the law and create illegal cartels. We’ve already examined the case of the lysine industry and in the upcoming Economics in Action, we’ll look at the chocolate industry.
A price war occurs when tacit collusion breaks down and prices collapse.
Because tacit collusion is often hard to achieve, most oligopolies charge prices that are well below what the same industry would charge if it were controlled by a monopolist—
Bitter Chocolate?
| interactive activity
The lysine price-
Prompted by disclosures by Cadbury Canada of its collusion with the other three major Canadian chocolate makers—
In the ensuing court proceedings, 13 Cadbury Canada executives voluntarily provided information about contacts with the other companies, including an episode in which a Nestlé Canada executive handed over an envelope containing details about a forthcoming price hike to a Cadbury Canada employee. And, according to affidavits filed in court, top executives of Hershey Canada, Nestlé Canada, and Mars Canada met secretly to set prices. In 2013, after protracted litigation, all four producers agreed to settle, paying a fine of more than $23 million to be distributed among consumers.
269
However, U.S. prosecutions were less successful. Many large U.S. grocery stores and snack retailers were convinced that they, too, had been the victims of collusion. So in 2010, one of those stores, SUPERVALU, filed a lawsuit against the American divisions of the big four chocolate makers.
In contrast to Canada, where the big four controlled a little less than 50% of the market, in the United States they controlled over 75%. SUPERVALU claimed that the American divisions of the big four had been fixing prices since 2002, regularly increasing prices by mid-
Indeed, the price of chocolate candy had been soaring in the United States, far in excess of the rate of inflation. Chocolate makers defended their actions, contending that they were simply passing on the higher costs of cocoa beans, dairy products, and sugar. And, as antitrust experts have pointed out, price collusion is often very difficult to prove because it is not illegal for producers to raise their prices at the same time. To prove collusion, there must be proof in the form of conversations or written agreements.
In March 2014 an American judge threw out the charges of collusion, stating that there was no evidence that executives at the big four chocolate producers were aware of the anti-
Oligopoly is a common market structure, one in which there are only a few firms, called oligopolists, in the industry.
Oligopoly is a form of imperfect competition and arises from the same forces that lead to monopoly, except in weaker form.
Some of the key issues in oligopoly can be understood by looking at the simplest case, a duopoly—
By acting as if they were a single monopolist, oligopolists can maximize their combined profits. So there is an incentive to form a cartel.
However, each firm has an incentive to cheat—
Oligopolies operate under legal restrictions in the form of antitrust policy. But many succeed in achieving tacit collusion, which occurs when firms, without any formal agreement, limit production and raise prices in a way that raises one anothers’ profits.
Tacit collusion is limited by a number of factors, including a large number of firms, complex products and pricing, differences in interests among firms, and bargaining power of buyers. When collusion breaks down, there is a price war.
1. Explain why each of the following industries is an oligopoly, not a perfectly competitive industry.
The world oil industry, where a few countries near the Persian Gulf control much of the world’s oil reserves
The world oil industry is an oligopoly because a few countries control a necessary resource for production, oil reserves.
The microprocessor industry, where two firms, Intel and its bitter rival AMD, dominate the technology
The microprocessor industry is an oligopoly because two firms possess superior technology and so dominate industry production.
The wide-
The wide-
2. Which of the following factors increase the likelihood that an oligopolist will collude with other firms in the industry? Which of these factors increase the likelihood that an oligopolist will act noncooperatively and raise output? Explain your answers.
The firm’s initial market share is small. (Hint: Think about the price effect.)
The firm is likely to act noncooperatively and raise output, which will generate a negative price effect. But because the firm’s current market share is small, the negative price effect will fall much more heavily on its rivals’ revenues than on its own. At the same time, the firm will benefit from a positive quantity effect.
The firm has a cost advantage over its rivals.
The firm is likely to act noncooperatively and raise output, which will generate a fall in price. Because its rivals have higher costs, they will lose money at the lower price while the firm continues to make profits. So the firm may be able to drive its rivals out of business by increasing its output.
3. Which of the following factors are likely to support the conclusion that there is tacit collusion in this industry? Which of these factors are not likely to support that conclusion? Explain your answers.
There has been considerable variation in the market shares of the firms in the industry over time.
This is not likely to be interpreted as evidence of tacit collusion. Considerable variation in market shares indicates that firms have been competing to capture one anothers’ business.
Firms in the industry build into their products unnecessary features that make it hard for consumers to switch from one company’s products to another company’s products.
This is not likely to be interpreted as evidence of tacit collusion. These features make it more unlikely that consumers will switch products in response to lower prices. So this is a way for firms to avoid any temptation to gain market share by lowering price. This is a form of product differentiation used to avoid direct competition.
Firms meet yearly to discuss their annual sales forecasts.
This is likely to be interpreted as evidence of tacit collusion. In the guise of discussing sales targets, firms can create a cartel by designating quantities to be produced by each firm.
Firms tend to adjust their prices upward at the same times.
This is likely to be interpreted as evidence of tacit collusion. By raising prices together, each firm in the industry is refusing to undercut its rivals by leaving its price unchanged or lowering it. Because it could gain market share by doing so, refusing to do it is evidence of tacit collusion.
Solutions appear at back of book.