The 2008 Crisis and Its Aftermath

As we’ve just seen, banking crises have typically been followed by major economic problems. How did the aftermath of the financial crisis of 2008 compare with this historical experience? The answer, unfortunately, is that history has proved a very good guide: once again, the economic damage from the financial crisis was both large and prolonged. And aftershocks from the crisis continue to shake the world economy today, after Lehman’s 2008 fall.

Severe Crisis, Slow Recovery

Figure 18-6 shows real GDP in the United States and the European Union, the world’s two largest economies, during the crisis and for four years afterward, with the peak pre-crisis quarter—the last quarter of 2007 for the United States, the first quarter of 2008 for the European Union—set equal to 100. What you can see is that both economies suffered severe downturns, shrinking more than 5%, followed by relatively slow recoveries. As of late 2012, Europe had not yet regained its pre-crisis level of output, and the United States was barely above its previous peak.

Crisis and Recovery in the United States and the European Union In the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis, aggregate output in the European Union and in the United States fell dramatically. Real GDP, shown here as an index with each economy’s peak pre-crisis quarter set to 100, declined by more than 5%. By late 2011, real GDP in the United States had only barely recovered to pre-crisis levels, and aggregate output in the European Union had still not reached its pre-crisis peak.
Sources: Bureau of Economic Analysis; Eurostat.

558

The severe slump and the slow recovery were very bad news for workers, since a healthy job market depends on an economy growing fast enough to accommodate both a growing workforce and rising productivity. Figure 18-7 shows two indicators of unemployment in the United States—the overall unemployment rate and the percentage of the unemployed who had been out of work 27 weeks or more—for the years 2007 through 2011. Both measures shot up during the crisis and remained very high years later, indicating a labor market in which it remained very hard to find a job. As of March 2013, unemployment remained high at 7.6%, with the percentage of long-term unemployed at 39%.

Unemployment in the Aftermath of the 2008 Crisis After 2008, the unemployment rate increased dramatically and remained high. Long-term unemployment, measured by the percentage of the unemployed who were out of work for 27 weeks or longer, increased at the same time. By 2011, almost half of all unemployed workers were long-term unemployed.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

This outcome was, sad to say, about what one should have expected given the severity of the initial financial shock and the historical experience with such shocks. In fact, the U.S. experience with unemployment almost exactly matched the average performance of past economies that had suffered major banking disruptions. America, observed Kenneth Rogoff (whose work we cited earlier), was experiencing a “garden variety severe financial crisis.”

559

Aftershocks in Europe

One important factor bedeviling hopes for recovery was the emergence of special difficulties in several European nations—difficulties that repeatedly raised the specter of a second financial crisis.

The 2008 crisis was caused by problems with private debt, mainly home loans, which then triggered a crisis of confidence in banks. In 2011 and 2012, fears of a second crisis were focused on public debt, specifically the public debts of Southern European countries plus Ireland.

Europe’s troubles first surfaced in Greece, a country with a long history of fiscal irresponsibility. In late 2009, it was revealed that a previous Greek government had understated the size of the budget deficits and the amount of government debt, prompting lenders to refuse further loans to Greece. Other European countries provided emergency loans to the Greek government in return for harsh budget cuts. But these budget cuts depressed the Greek economy, and by late 2011 there was general agreement that Greece could not pay back its debts in full.

By itself, this was probably a manageable shock for the European economy since Greece accounts for less than 3% of European GDP. Unfortunately, foot-dragging by European officials in confronting Greece’s problems and the effects of the harsh budget cuts on the Greek economy spooked investors. By the fall of 2011, the crisis had spread beyond the Greek borders, hitting two major European economies: Spain and Italy.

Figure 18-8 shows a measure of pressure on Italy and Spain during the 2008 and 2011 crises: the difference between interest rates on 10-year bonds issued by the two nations’ governments and interest rates on German debt, which most people consider a safe investment. Because all three countries use the same currency, the euro, these rates would all be the same if Italian and Spanish government debt were considered as safe as German government debt. The rise in “spreads” therefore indicates a growing perception of risk.

Interest Spread Against German 10-Year Bonds One indicator of investors’ perceptions of the risk of government default is the spread of interest rates on government bonds between that country and a country that is perceived as a safe investment. The spread of the interest rates on 10-year government bonds for Italy and Spain, measured against the interest rate on German bonds, rose as investors’ fears of default by Italy and Spain increased.
Source: Eurostat.

Spain’s fiscal problems were mainly fallout from the 2008 crisis. Before that crisis, Spain seemed to be in very good fiscal condition, with low debt and a budget surplus. However, Spain, like Ireland, had a huge housing bubble between 2000 and 2007. When the bubble burst, the Spanish economy fell into a deep slump, depressing tax receipts and causing large budget deficits. At the same time, there were worries that the Spanish government might eventually have to spend large amounts bailing out banks. As a result, investors began worrying about the solvency of the Spanish government and a possible default, driving up interest rates.

560

Italy’s case was somewhat different. Italy has long had high levels of public debt as a percentage of GDP, but it has not run large deficits in recent years; as late as the spring of 2010 its fiscal position looked fairly stable. At that point, however, investors began to have doubts about the Italian government’s solvency, in part because in the aftermath of the 2008 crisis the Italian economy was growing very slowly—too slowly, it was feared, to generate enough tax revenue to repay its public debt. These doubts drove up interest rates on Italian public debt, and this in turn created a vicious circle: higher interest payments, caused by fears about Italian government solvency, worsened Italy’s fiscal position even further and pushed it closer to the edge.

At the time of writing, Greece had defaulted on its government bonds, Spanish youth unemployment was over 50%, and it was unclear how much worse the European situation would get. But Europe’s difficulties reinforced the sense that the damage from the 2008 financial crisis was by no means over.

The Stimulus–Austerity Debate

The persistence of economic difficulties after the 2008 financial crisis led to fierce debates about appropriate policy responses. Broadly speaking, economists and policy makers were divided as to whether the situation called for more fiscal stimulus—expansionary fiscal measures such as more government spending and possibly tax cuts to promote spending and reduce unemployment—or for fiscal “austerity,” contractionary fiscal measures such as spending cuts and possibly tax increases to reduce budget deficits.

The proponents of more stimulus pointed to the continuing poor performance of major economies, arguing that the combination of high unemployment and relatively low inflation clearly pointed to the need for expansionary policies. And since monetary policy was limited by the zero bound for interest rates, stimulus proponents advocated expansionary fiscal policy to fill the gap.

The austerity camp took a very different view. Strongly influenced by the solvency troubles of Greece, Ireland, Spain, and Italy, they argued that the common source of all the problems were high levels of government deficits and debts. In their view, countries like the United States that continued to run large government deficits several years after the 2008 crisis were at risk of suffering a similar loss of investor confidence in their ability to repay their debts. Moreover, austerity advocates claimed that cuts in government spending would not actually be contractionary because they would improve investor confidence and keep interest rates on government debt low.

The British economy was decimated by the aftermath of the 2008 crisis coupled with government austerity measures.
Oli Scarff/Getty Images

Each side of the debate argued that recent experience refuted the other side’s claims. Austerity proponents argued that the persistence of high unemployment despite the fiscal stimulus programs adopted by the United States and other major economies in 2009 showed that stimulus doesn’t work. Stimulus advocates argued that these programs were simply inadequate in size, pointing out that many economists had warned of their inadequacy from the start. Stimulus advocates further argued that warnings about the dangers of deficits were overblown, that far from rising, borrowing costs for Japan, the United States, and Britain—nations that, unlike the troubled European debtors, still had their own currencies with all the flexibility that implies—had fallen to record lows. And they dismissed claims that spending cuts would raise confidence as mainly fantasy.

At the time of writing, neither side was giving much ground. Clearly, any resolution of the debate would hinge on future economic developments and how they were interpreted.

561

The Lesson of the Post-Crisis Slump

Almost all major economies had great difficulty dealing with the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis—high unemployment, low growth and, for some, solvency concerns, and high interest rates on public debt.

Clearly, then, the best way to avoid the terrible problems that arise after a financial crisis is not to have a crisis in the first place. How can you do that? In part, one might hope, through better regulation of financial institutions. We turn next to attempts at regulatory reform.

Austerity Britain

An election in May 2010 led to a shift in power in Britain, with a Labour Party government replaced by a coalition dominated by the Conservative Party under the new prime minister, David Cameron. The new government was firmly committed to the austerity side of the great post-crisis policy debate, and it changed policy accordingly.

Unlike Greece or Ireland, Britain wasn’t under any immediate pressure to slash its budget deficit. Like the U.S. government, the British government was still able to borrow cheaply despite its large deficit. And the British economy was, if anything, even more depressed than the U.S. one, with fewer signs of recovery. The Cameron government believed, however, that preemptive cuts in public spending combined with some tax increases were necessary to preserve investor confidence and also that such cuts could boost the economy by improving confidence.

How have these policies performed? As of mid-2012, the experiment in austerity had yielded disappointing results. British economic growth was weak—in fact, considerably weaker than in the United States, even though U.S. performance was lackluster. And as Figure 18-9 shows, the hoped-for surge in business confidence that austerity measures were supposed to generate had failed to materialize.

Business Confidence in Britain
Source: Grant Thornton, UK Business Confidence Monitor.

Quick Review

  • Economic damage from the financial crisis of 2008 was both large and prolonged. Aftershocks from the crisis continue to shake the world economy.
  • The world’s two largest economies, the United States and the European Union, suffered severe downturns, shrinking more than 5%, followed by relatively slow recoveries. The severe slump and the slow recovery were very bad news for workers.
  • The persistence of economic difficulties after the 2008 financial crisis led to severe solvency concerns for several European countries. A fierce debate erupted over whether fiscal stimulus or fiscal austerity was the right policy prescription.

Check Your Understanding 18-4

  1. Question

    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
    Standard macroeconomics the kind we've discussed in this book - would say that faced with an economic slump, a government should adopt expansionary policies to increase aggregate demand. France, however, was doing just the opposite, responding to a weaker economy with a contractionary fiscal policy that would make the economy even weaker. This shows that the French government had aligned itself with the austerity view, believing that it was more important to assure markets of its solvency than it was to support the economy.