Two Key Concepts: Marginal Cost and Average Cost

We’ve just learned how to derive a firm’s total cost curve from its production function. Our next step is to take a deeper look at total cost by deriving two extremely useful measures: marginal cost and average cost. As we’ll see, these two measures of the cost of production have a somewhat surprising relationship to each other. Moreover, they will prove to be vitally important in Chapter 7, where we will use them to analyze the firm’s output decision and the market supply curve.

Marginal Cost

The marginal cost of producing a good or service is the additional cost incurred by producing one more unit of that good or service.

Marginal cost is the change in total cost generated by producing one more unit of output. We’ve already seen that the marginal product of an input is easiest to calculate if data on output are available in increments of one unit of that input. Similarly, marginal cost is easiest to calculate if data on total cost are available in increments of one unit of output. When the data come in less convenient increments, it’s still possible to calculate marginal cost. But for the sake of simplicity, let’s work with an example in which the data come in convenient one-unit increments.

Selena’s Gourmet Salsas produces bottled salsa and Table 6-1 shows how its costs per day depend on the number of cases of salsa it produces per day. The firm has fixed cost of $108 per day, shown in the second column, which represents the daily cost of its food-preparation equipment. The third column shows the variable cost, and the fourth column shows the total cost. Panel (a) of Figure 6-6 plots the total cost curve. Like the total cost curve for George and Martha’s farm in Figure 6-4, this curve slopes upward, getting steeper as you move up it to the right.

Table : TABLE 6-1 Costs at Selena’s Gourmet Salsas
Total Cost and Marginal Cost Curves for Selena’s Gourmet Salsas Panel (a) shows the total cost curve from Table 6-1. Like the total cost curve in Figure 6-4, it slopes upward and gets steeper as we move up it to the right. Panel (b) shows the marginal cost curve. It also slopes upward, reflecting diminishing returns to the variable input.

190

The significance of the slope of the total cost curve is shown by the fifth column of Table 6-1, which calculates marginal cost: the additional cost of each additional unit. The general formula for marginal cost is:

or

As in the case of marginal product, marginal cost is equal to “rise” (the increase in total cost) divided by “run” (the increase in the quantity of output). So just as marginal product is equal to the slope of the total product curve, marginal cost is equal to the slope of the total cost curve.

Now we can understand why the total cost curve gets steeper as we move up it to the right: as you can see in Table 6-1, marginal cost at Selena’s Gourmet Salsas rises as output increases. Panel (b) of Figure 6-6 shows the marginal cost curve corresponding to the data in Table 6-1. Notice that, as in Figure 6-2, we plot the marginal cost for increasing output from 0 to 1 case of salsa halfway between 0 and 1, the marginal cost for increasing output from 1 to 2 cases of salsa halfway between 1 and 2, and so on.

Why does the marginal cost curve slope upward? Because there are diminishing returns to inputs in this example. As output increases, the marginal product of the variable input declines. This implies that more and more of the variable input must be used to produce each additional unit of output as the amount of output already produced rises. And since each unit of the variable input must be paid for, the additional cost per additional unit of output also rises.

In addition, recall that the flattening of the total product curve is also due to diminishing returns: the marginal product of an input falls as more of that input is used if the quantities of other inputs are fixed. The flattening of the total product curve as output increases and the steepening of the total cost curve as output increases are just flip-sides of the same phenomenon. That is, as output increases, the marginal cost of output also increases because the marginal product of the variable input decreases.

191

We will return to marginal cost in Chapter 7, when we consider the firm’s profit-maximizing output decision. Our next step is to introduce another measure of cost: average cost.

Average Total Cost

Average total cost, often referred to simply as average cost, is total cost divided by quantity of output produced.

In addition to total cost and marginal cost, it’s useful to calculate another measure, average total cost, often simply called average cost. The average total cost is total cost divided by the quantity of output produced; that is, it is equal to total cost per unit of output. If we let ATC denote average total cost, the equation looks like this:

Average total cost is important because it tells the producer how much the average or typical unit of output costs to produce. Marginal cost, meanwhile, tells the producer how much one more unit of output costs to produce. Although they may look very similar, these two measures of cost typically differ. And confusion between them is a major source of error in economics, both in the classroom and in real life, as illustrated by the upcoming Economics in Action.

Table 6-2 uses data from Selena’s Gourmet Salsas to calculate average total cost. For example, the total cost of producing 4 cases of salsa is $300, consisting of $108 in fixed cost and $192 in variable cost (from Table 6-1). So the average total cost of producing 4 cases of salsa is $300/4 = $75. You can see from Table 6-2 that as quantity of output increases, average total cost first falls, then rises.

Quantity of salsa Q (cases) Total cost TC Average total cost of case ATC = TC/Q Average fixed cost of case AFC = FC/Q Average variable cost of case AVC = VC/Q
1  $120 $120.00 $108.00 $12.00
2   156   78.00   54.00  24.00
3   216   72.00   36.00  36.00
4   300   75.00   27.00  48.00
5   408   81.60   21.60  60.00
6   540   90.00   18.00  72.00
7   696  99.43   15.43  84.00
8   876  109.50   13.50  96.00
9 1,080 120.00   12.00 108.00
10 1,308 130.80   10.80 120.00
Table : TABLE 6-2 Average Costs for Selena’s Gourmet Salsas

192

A U-shaped average total cost curve falls at low levels of output, then rises at higher levels.

Figure 6-7 plots that data to yield the average total cost curve, which shows how average total cost depends on output. As before, cost in dollars is measured on the vertical axis and quantity of output is measured on the horizontal axis. The average total cost curve has a distinctive U shape that corresponds to how average total cost first falls and then rises as output increases. Economists believe that such U-shaped average total cost curves are the norm for producers in many industries.

Average Total Cost Curve for Selena’s Gourmet Salsas The average total cost curve at Selena’s Gourmet Salsas is U-shaped. At low levels of output, average total cost falls because the “spreading effect” of falling average fixed cost dominates the “diminishing returns effect” of rising average variable cost. At higher levels of output, the opposite is true and average total cost rises. At point M, corresponding to an output of three cases of salsa per day, average total cost is at its minimum level, the minimum average total cost.

Average fixed cost is the fixed cost per unit of output.

Average variable cost is the variable cost per unit of output.

To help our understanding of why the average total cost curve is U-shaped, Table 6-2 breaks average total cost into its two underlying components, average fixed cost and average variable cost. Average fixed cost, or AFC, is fixed cost divided by the quantity of output, also known as the fixed cost per unit of output. For example, if Selena’s Gourmet Salsas produces 4 cases of salsa, average fixed cost is $108/4 = $27 per case. Average variable cost, or AVC, is variable cost divided by the quantity of output, also known as variable cost per unit of output. At an output of 4 cases, average variable cost is $192/4 = $48 per case. Writing these in the form of equations:

193

Average total cost is the sum of average fixed cost and average variable cost. It has a U shape because these components move in opposite directions as output rises.

Average fixed cost falls as more output is produced because the numerator (the fixed cost) is a fixed number but the denominator (the quantity of output) increases as more is produced. Another way to think about this relationship is that, as more output is produced, the fixed cost is spread over more units of output; the end result is that the fixed cost per unit of output—the average fixed cost—falls. You can see this effect in the fourth column of Table 6-2: average fixed cost drops continuously as output increases.

Average variable cost, however, rises as output increases. As we’ve seen, this reflects diminishing returns to the variable input: each additional unit of output incurs more variable cost to produce than the previous unit. So variable cost rises at a faster rate than the quantity of output increases.

So increasing output has two opposing effects on average total cost—the “spreading effect” and the “diminishing returns effect”:

At low levels of output, the spreading effect is very powerful because even small increases in output cause large reductions in average fixed cost. So at low levels of output, the spreading effect dominates the diminishing returns effect and causes the average total cost curve to slope downward. But when output is large, average fixed cost is already quite small, so increasing output further has only a very small spreading effect. Diminishing returns, however, usually grow increasingly important as output rises. As a result, when output is large, the diminishing returns effect dominates the spreading effect, causing the average total cost curve to slope upward. At the bottom of the U-shaped average total cost curve, point M in Figure 6-7, the two effects exactly balance each other. At this point average total cost is at its minimum level, the minimum average total cost.

Figure 6-8 brings together in a single picture four members of the family of cost curves that we have derived from the total cost curve for Selena’s Gourmet Salsas: the marginal cost curve (MC), the average total cost curve (ATC), the average variable cost curve (AVC), and the average fixed cost curve (AFC). All are based on the information in Tables 6-1 and 6-2. As before, cost is measured on the vertical axis and the quantity of output is measured on the horizontal axis.

Marginal Cost and Average Cost Curves for Selena’s Gourmet Salsas Here we have the family of cost curves for Selena’s Gourmet Salsas: the marginal cost curve (MC), the average total cost curve (ATC), the average variable cost curve (AVC), and the average fixed cost curve (AFC). Note that the average total cost curve is U-shaped and the marginal cost curve crosses the average total cost curve at the bottom of the U, point M, corresponding to the minimum average total cost from Table 6-2 and Figure 6-7.

Let’s take a moment to note some features of the various cost curves. First of all, marginal cost slopes upward—the result of diminishing returns that make an additional unit of output more costly to produce than the one before. Average variable cost also slopes upward—again, due to diminishing returns—but is flatter than the marginal cost curve. This is because the higher cost of an additional unit of output is averaged across all units, not just the additional units, in the average variable cost measure. Meanwhile, average fixed cost slopes downward because of the spreading effect.

194

Finally, notice that the marginal cost curve intersects the average total cost curve from below, crossing it at its lowest point, point M in Figure 6-8. This last feature is our next subject of study.

Minimum Average Total Cost

The minimum-cost output is the quantity of output at which average total cost is lowest—the bottom of the U-shaped average total cost curve.

For a U-shaped average total cost curve, average total cost is at its minimum level at the bottom of the U. Economists call the quantity of output that corresponds to the minimum average total cost the minimum-cost output. In the case of Selena’s Gourmet Salsas, the minimum-cost output is three cases of salsa per day.

In Figure 6-8, the bottom of the U is at the level of output at which the marginal cost curve crosses the average total cost curve from below. Is this an accident? No—it reflects general principles that are always true about a firm’s marginal cost and average total cost curves:

To understand these principles, think about how your grade in one course—say, a 3.0 in physics—affects your overall grade point average. If your GPA before receiving that grade was more than 3.0, the new grade lowers your average.

Similarly, if marginal cost—the cost of producing one more unit—is less than average total cost, producing that extra unit lowers average total cost. This is shown in Figure 6-9 by the movement from A1 to A2. In this case, the marginal cost of producing an additional unit of output is low, as indicated by the point MCL on the marginal cost curve. When the cost of producing the next unit of output is less than average total cost, increasing production reduces average total cost. So any quantity of output at which marginal cost is less than average total cost must be on the downward-sloping segment of the U.

The Relationship Between the Average Total Cost and the Marginal Cost Curves To see why the marginal cost curve (MC) must cut through the average total cost curve at the minimum average total cost (point M), corresponding to the minimum-cost output, we look at what happens if marginal cost is different from average total cost. If marginal cost is less than average total cost, an increase in output must reduce average total cost, as in the movement from A1 to A2. If marginal cost is greater than average total cost, an increase in output must increase average total cost, as in the movement from B1 to B2.

195

But if your grade in physics is more than the average of your previous grades, this new grade raises your GPA. Similarly, if marginal cost is greater than average total cost, producing that extra unit raises average total cost. This is illustrated by the movement from B1 to B2 in Figure 6-9, where the marginal cost, MCH, is higher than average total cost. So any quantity of output at which marginal cost is greater than average total cost must be on the upward-sloping segment of the U.

Finally, if a new grade is exactly equal to your previous GPA, the additional grade neither raises nor lowers that average—it stays the same. This corresponds to point M in Figure 6-9: when marginal cost equals average total cost, we must be at the bottom of the U, because only at that point is average total cost neither falling nor rising.

Does the Marginal Cost Curve Always Slope Upward?

Up to this point, we have emphasized the importance of diminishing returns, which lead to a marginal product curve that always slopes downward and a marginal cost curve that always slopes upward. In practice, however, economists believe that marginal cost curves often slope downward as a firm increases its production from zero up to some low level, sloping upward only at higher levels of production: they look like the curve MC in Figure 6-10.

More Realistic Cost Curves A realistic marginal cost curve has a “swoosh” shape. Starting from a very low output level, marginal cost often falls as the firm increases output. That’s because hiring additional workers allows greater specialization of their tasks and leads to increasing returns. Once specialization is achieved, however, diminishing returns to additional workers set in and marginal cost rises. The corresponding average variable cost curve is now U-shaped, like the average total cost curve.

This initial downward slope occurs because a firm often finds that, when it starts with only a very small number of workers, employing more workers and expanding output allows its workers to specialize in various tasks. This, in turn, lowers the firm’s marginal cost as it expands output. For example, one individual producing salsa would have to perform all the tasks involved: selecting and preparing the ingredients, mixing the salsa, bottling and labeling it, packing it into cases, and so on. As more workers are employed, they can divide the tasks, with each worker specializing in one or a few aspects of salsa-making. This specialization leads to increasing returns to the hiring of additional workers and results in a marginal cost curve that initially slopes downward. But once there are enough workers to have completely exhausted the benefits of further specialization, diminishing returns to labor set in and the marginal cost curve changes direction and slopes upward. So typical marginal cost curves actually have the “swoosh” shape shown by MC in Figure 6-10. For the same reason, average variable cost curves typically look like AVC in Figure 6-10: they are U-shaped rather than strictly upward sloping.

196

However, as Figure 6-10 also shows, the key features we saw from the example of Selena’s Gourmet Salsas remain true: the average total cost curve is U-shaped, and the marginal cost curve passes through the point of minimum average total cost.

Don’T Put Out the Welcome Mat

Housing developments have traditionally been considered as American as apple pie. With our abundant supply of undeveloped land, real estate developers have long found it profitable to buy big parcels of land, build a large number of homes, and create entire new communities. But what is profitable for developers is not necessarily good for the existing residents.

In the past few years, real estate developers have encountered increasingly stiff resistance from local residents because of the additional costs—the marginal costs—imposed on existing homeowners from new developments. Let’s look at why.

In the United States, a large percentage of the funding for local services comes from taxes paid by local homeowners. In a sense, the local township authority uses those taxes to “produce” municipal services for the town. The overall level of property taxes is set to reflect the costs of providing those services. The highest service cost by far, in most communities, is the cost of public education.

New housing developments lead to higher taxes for everyone in the neighborhood.
Visions of America, LLC/Stock Connection

The local tax rate that new homeowners pay on their new homes is the same as what existing homeowners pay on their older homes. That tax rate reflects the current total cost of services, and the taxes that an average homeowner pays reflect the average total cost of providing services to a household. The average total cost of providing services is based on the town’s use of existing facilities, such as the existing school buildings, the existing number of teachers, the existing fleet of school buses, and so on.

197

But when a large development of homes is constructed, those facilities are no longer adequate: new schools must be built, new teachers hired, and so on. The quantity of output increases. So the marginal cost of providing municipal services per household associated with a new, large-scale development turns out to be much higher than the average total cost per household of existing homes. As a result, new developments and facilities cause everyone’s local tax rate to go up, just as you would expect from Figure 6-9. A recent study in Massachusetts estimated that a $250,000 new home with one school-age child imposed an additional cost to the community of $5,527 per year over and above the taxes paid by the new homeowners. As a result, in many towns across America, potential new housing developments and newcomers are now facing a distinctly chilly reception.

Quick Review

  • Marginal cost—the change in total cost with a change in output—is equal to the slope of the total cost curve. Diminishing returns cause the marginal cost curve to slope upward.
  • Average total cost (or average cost) is equal to the sum of average fixed cost and average variable cost. When the U-shaped average total cost curve slopes downward, the spreading effect dominates: fixed cost is spread over more units of output. When it slopes upward, the diminishing returns effect dominates: an additional unit of output requires more variable inputs.
  • Marginal cost is equal to average total cost at the minimum-cost output. At higher output levels, marginal cost is greater than average total cost and average total cost is rising. At lower output levels, marginal cost is lower than average total cost and average total cost is falling.
  • At low levels of output there are often increasing returns to the variable input due to the benefits of specialization, making the marginal cost curve “swoosh”-shaped: initially sloping downward before sloping upward.

Check Your Understanding 6-2

    • Question

      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
      See the accompanying table. Average variable cost for Q pies is equal to variable cost for the Q pies divided by Q; for example, the average variable cost of five pies is $13.19/5, or approximately $2.64.
    • Question

      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
      The spreading effect dominates the diminishing returns effect when average total cost is falling: the fall in AFC dominates the rise in AVC for pies 1 to 4. The diminishing returns effect dominates when average total cost is rising: the rise in AVC dominates the fall in AFC for pies 5 and 6.
    • Question

      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
      Alicia’s minimum-cost output is 4 pies; this generates the lowest average total cost, $4.28. When output is less than 4, the marginal cost of a pie is less than the average total cost of the pies already produced. So making an additional pie lowers average total cost. For example, the marginal cost of pie 3 is $2.25, whereas the average total cost of pies 1 and 2 is $5.75. So making pie 3 lowers average total cost to $4.58, equal to (2 x $5.75 + $2.25)/3. When output is more than 4, the marginal cost of a pie is greater than the average total cost of the pies already produced. Consequently, making an additional pie raises average total cost. So, although the marginal cost of pie 6 is $7.59, the average total cost of pies 1 through 5 is $4.44. Making pie 6 raises average total cost to $4.96, equal to (5 x $4.44 + $7.59)/6.

Solutions appear at back of book.