Let’s look at the market for used textbooks, starting with the buyers. The key point, as we’ll see in a minute, is that the demand curve is derived from their tastes or preferences—
A used book is not as good as a new book—
A consumer’s willingness to pay for a good is the maximum price at which he or she would buy that good.
Let’s define a potential buyer’s willingness to pay as the maximum price at which he or she would buy a good, in this case a used textbook. An individual won’t buy the book if it costs more than this amount but is eager to do so if it costs less. If the price is just equal to an individual’s willingness to pay, he or she is indifferent between buying and not buying.
Table 5A-1 shows five potential buyers of a used book that costs $100 new, listed in order of their willingness to pay. At one extreme is Aleisha, who will buy a second-
5A-1
Consumer Surplus If Price of a Used Textbook = $30
Potential buyer |
Willingness to pay |
Price paid |
Individual consumer surplus = Willingness to pay − Price paid |
---|---|---|---|
Aleisha |
$59 |
$30 |
$29 |
Brad |
45 |
30 |
15 |
Claudia |
35 |
30 |
5 |
Darren |
25 |
− |
− |
Edwina |
10 |
− |
− |
All buyers |
|
|
Total consumer surplus = $49 |
TABLE 5A-1 Consumer Surplus If Price of a Used Textbook = $30
How many of these five students will actually buy a used book? It depends on the price. If the price of a used book is $55, only Aleisha buys one; if the price is $40, Aleisha and Brad both buy used books, and so on. So the information in the table on willingness to pay also defines the demand schedule for used textbooks.
Suppose that the campus bookstore makes used textbooks available at a price of $30. In that case Aleisha, Brad, and Claudia will buy books. Do they gain from their purchases, and if so, how much?
The answer, also shown in Table 5A-1, is that each student who purchases a book does achieve a net gain but that the amount of the gain differs among students.
Aleisha would have been willing to pay $59, so her net gain is $59 − $30 = $29. Brad would have been willing to pay $45, so his net gain is $45 − $30 = $15. Claudia would have been willing to pay $35, so her net gain is $35 − $30 = $5. Darren and Edwina, however, won’t be willing to buy a used book at a price of $30, so they neither gain nor lose.
Individual consumer surplus is the net gain to an individual buyer from the purchase of a good. It is equal to the difference between the buyer’s willingness to pay and the price paid.
The net gain that a buyer achieves from the purchase of a good is called that buyer’s individual consumer surplus. What we learn from this example is that whenever a buyer pays a price less than his or her willingness to pay, the buyer achieves some individual consumer surplus.
Total consumer surplus is the sum of the individual consumer surpluses of all the buyers of a good in a market.
The sum of the individual consumer surpluses achieved by all the buyers of a good is known as the total consumer surplus achieved in the market. In Table 5A-1, the total consumer surplus is the sum of the individual consumer surpluses achieved by Aleisha, Brad, and Claudia: $29 + $15 + $5 = $49.
The term consumer surplus is often used to refer to both individual and total consumer surplus.
Economists often use the term consumer surplus to refer to both individual and total consumer surplus. We will follow this practice; it will always be clear in context whether we are referring to the consumer surplus achieved by an individual or by all buyers.
Total consumer surplus can be represented graphically. As we saw in Chapter 3, we can use the demand schedule to derive the market demand curve shown in Figure 5A-1. Because we are considering only a small number of consumers, this curve doesn’t look like the smooth demand curves of Chapter 3, where markets contained hundreds or thousands of consumers. Instead, this demand curve is stepped, with alternating horizontal and vertical segments.
5A-1
Consumer Surplus in the Used-
Each horizontal segment—
In addition to Aleisha, Brad and Claudia will also each buy a book when the price is $30. Like Aleisha, they benefit from their purchases, though not as much, because they each have a lower willingness to pay. Figure 5A-1 also shows the consumer surplus gained by Brad and Claudia; again, this can be measured by the areas of the appropriate rectangles. Darren and Edwina, because they do not buy books at a price of $30, receive no consumer surplus.
The total consumer surplus achieved in this market is just the sum of the individual consumer surpluses received by Aleisha, Brad, and Claudia. So total consumer surplus is equal to the combined area of the three rectangles—
This illustrates the following general principle: the total consumer surplus generated by purchases of a good at a given price is equal to the area below the demand curve but above that price. The same principle applies regardless of the number of consumers.
For large markets, such as the market for smart phones that was used in the chapter, this graphical representation of consumer surplus becomes extremely helpful. Consider, for example, the sales of iPhones to millions of potential buyers. Each potential buyer has a maximum price that he or she is willing to pay. With so many potential buyers, the demand curve will be smooth, like the one shown in Figure 5A-2.
5A-2
Consumer Surplus
Suppose that at a price of $500, a total of 1 million iPhones are purchased. How much do consumers gain from being able to buy those 1 million iPhones? We could answer that question by calculating the consumer surplus of each individual buyer and then adding these numbers up to arrive at a total. But it is much easier just to look at Figure 5A-2 and use the fact that the total consumer surplus is equal to the shaded area. As in our original example, consumer surplus is equal to the area below the demand curve but above the price. (You can refresh your memory on how to calculate the area of a right triangle by reviewing the appendix to Chapter 2.)