Up to this point, we have treated fixed cost as completely outside the control of a firm because we have focused on the short run. But as we noted earlier, all inputs are variable in the long run: this means that in the long run fixed cost may also be varied. In the long run, in other words, a firm’s fixed cost becomes a variable it can choose. For example, given time, Selena’s Gourmet Salsas can acquire additional food-
Let’s begin by supposing that Selena’s Gourmet Salsas is considering whether to acquire additional food-
The table in Figure 11-11 shows how acquiring an additional machine affects costs. In our original example, we assumed that Selena’s Gourmet Salsas had a fixed cost of $108. The left half of the table shows variable cost as well as total cost and average total cost assuming a fixed cost of $108. The average total cost curve for this level of fixed cost is given by ATC1 in Figure 11-11. Let’s compare that to a situation in which the firm buys additional food-
From the figure you can see that when output is small, 4 cases of salsa per day or fewer, average total cost is smaller when Selena forgoes the additional equipment and maintains the lower fixed cost of $108: ATC1 lies below ATC2. For example, at 3 cases per day, average total cost is $72 without the additional machinery and $90 with the additional machinery. But as output increases beyond 4 cases per day, the firm’s average total cost is lower if it acquires the additional equipment, raising its fixed cost to $216. For example, at 9 cases of salsa per day, average total cost is $120 when fixed cost is $108 but only $78 when fixed cost is $216.
Why does average total cost change like this when fixed cost increases? When output is low, the increase in fixed cost from the additional equipment outweighs the reduction in variable cost from higher worker productivity—
In general, for each output level there is some choice of fixed cost that minimizes the firm’s average total cost for that output level. So when the firm has a desired output level that it expects to maintain over time, it should choose the level of fixed cost optimal for that level—
Now that we are studying a situation in which fixed cost can change, we need to take time into account when discussing average total cost. All of the average total cost curves we have considered until now are defined for a given level of fixed cost—
For most firms, it is realistic to assume that there are many possible choices of fixed cost, not just two. The implication: for such a firm, many possible short-
At any given point in time, a firm will find itself on one of its short-
The long-
Suppose we do a thought experiment and calculate the lowest possible average total cost that can be achieved for each output level if the firm were to choose its fixed cost for each output level. Economists have given this thought experiment a name: the long-
We can now draw the distinction between the short run and the long run more fully. In the long run, when a producer has had time to choose the fixed cost appropriate for its desired level of output, that producer will be at some point on the long-
Figure 11-12 illustrates this point. The curve ATCļ shows short-
Suppose that Selena initially chose to be on ATC6. If she actually produces 6 cases of salsa per day, her firm will be at point C on both its short-
Suppose, conversely, that Selena ends up producing 9 cases per day even though she initially chose to be on ATC6. In the short run her average total cost is indicated by point Y on ATC6. But she would be better off purchasing more equipment and incurring a higher fixed cost in order to reduce her variable cost and move to ATC9. This would allow her to reach point X on the long-
The distinction between short-
There are increasing returns to scale when long-
What determines the shape of the long-
There are decreasing returns to scale when long-
As you can see in Figure 11-12, Selena’s Gourmet Salsas experiences increasing returns to scale over output levels ranging from 0 up to5 cases of salsa per day—
There are constant returns to scale when long-
There is also a third possible relationship between long-
What explains these scale effects in production? The answer ultimately lies in the firm’s technology of production. Increasing returns often arise from the increased specialization that larger output levels allow—
Another source of increasing returns is very large initial setup cost; in some industries—
A third source of increasing returns, found in certain high-
Decreasing returns—
If a firm is to make the best decisions about how much to produce, it has to understand how its costs relate to the quantity of output it chooses to produce. Table 11-3 provides a quick summary of the concepts and measures of cost you have learned about.
There’s No Business Like Snow Business
Anyone who has lived both in a snowy city, like Chicago, and in a city that only occasionally experiences significant snowfall, like Washington, D.C., is aware of the differences in total cost that arise from making different choices about fixed cost.
In Washington, even a minor snowfall—
In this sense Washington and Chicago are like two producers who expect to produce different levels of output, where the “output” is snow removal. Washington, which rarely has significant snow, has chosen a low level of fixed cost in the form of snow-
In the long run, firms choose fixed cost according to expected output. Higher fixed cost reduces average total cost when output is high. Lower fixed cost reduces average total cost when output is low.
There are many possible short-
A firm that has fully adjusted its fixed cost for its output level will operate at a point that lies on both its current short-
Scale effects arise from the technology of production. Increasing returns to scale tend to make firms larger. Decreasing returns to scale tend to limit their size. With constant returns to scale, scale has no effect.
The accompanying table shows three possible combinations of fixed cost and average variable cost. Average variable cost is constant in this example (it does not vary with the quantity of output produced).
For each of the three choices, calculate the average total cost of producing 12,000, 22,000, and 30,000 units. For each of these quantities, which choice results in the lowest average total cost?
Suppose that the firm, which has historically produced 12,000 units, experiences a sharp, permanent increase in demand that leads it to produce 22,000 units. Explain how its average total cost will change in the short run and in the long run.
Choice |
Fixed cost |
Average variable cost |
---|---|---|
1 |
$8,000 |
$1.00 |
2 |
12,000 |
0.75 |
3 |
24,000 |
0.25 |
Explain what the firm should do instead if it believes the change in demand is temporary.
In each of the following cases, explain what kind of scale effects you think the firm will experience and why.
A telemarketing firm in which employees make sales calls using computers and telephones
An interior design firm in which design projects are based on the expertise of the firm’s owner
A diamond-
Draw a graph like Figure 11-12 and insert a short-
Solutions appear at back of book.
For those who like to procrastinate when it comes to holiday shopping, the rise of e-
E-
Behind these technological advances, however, lies an intense debate: people versus robots. Amazon.com has relied on a large staff of temporary human workers to get it through the previous holiday seasons, often quadrupling its staff and operating 24 hours a day. In contrast, CrateandBarrel.com only doubled its workforce, thanks to a cadre of orange robots that allows each worker to do the work of six people.
But Amazon.com is set to increase its robotic work force in the future. In May 2012, Amazon.com bought Kiva Systems, the leader in order fulfillment robotics, for $775 million, with the hope of tailoring Kiva’s systems to fit Amazon.com’s warehouse and fulfillment needs.
Although many retailers—
As one industry analyst noted, an obstacle to the purchase of a robotic system for many e-
QUESTIONS FOR THOUGHT