New Jersey is the most densely populated state in the country, lying along the northeastern corridor, an area of almost continuous development stretching from Washington, D.C., to Boston. Yet a drive through New Jersey reveals a surprising feature: acre upon acre of farmland, growing everything from corn to pumpkins to the famous Jersey tomatoes. This situation is no accident: starting in 1961, New Jerseyans have voted in a series of measures that subsidize farmers to permanently preserve their farmland rather than sell it to developers. By 2013, the Green Acres Program, administered by the state, had preserved over 640,000 acres of open space.
Why have New Jersey citizens voted to raise their own taxes to subsidize the preservation of farmland? Because they believe that preserved farmland in an already heavily developed state provides external benefits, such as natural beauty, access to fresh food, and the conservation of wild bird populations. In addition, preservation alleviates the external costs that come with more development, such as pressure on roads, water supplies, and municipal services—
In this section we’ll explore the topics of external benefits and positive externalities. They are, in many ways, the mirror images of external costs and negative externalities. Left to its own, the market will produce too little of a good (in this case, preserved New Jersey farmland) that confers external benefits on others. But society as a whole is better off when policies are adopted that increase the supply of such a good.
Preserved farmland yields both benefits and costs to society. In the absence of government intervention, the farmer who wants to sell his land incurs all the costs of preservation—
Figure 16-4 illustrates society’s problem. The marginal social cost of preserved farmland, shown by the MSC curve, is the additional cost imposed on society by an additional acre of such farmland. This represents the forgone profits that would have accrued to farmers if they had sold their land to developers. The line is upward sloping because when very few acres are preserved and there is plenty of land available for development, the profit that could be made from selling an acre to a developer is small. But as the number of preserved acres increases and few are left for development, the amount a developer is willing to pay for them, and therefore the forgone profit, increases as well.
The MSB curve represents the marginal social benefit of preserved farmland. It is the additional benefit that accrues to society—
As Figure 16-4 shows, the socially optimal point, O, occurs when the marginal social cost and the marginal social benefit are equalized—
The market alone will not provide QOPT acres of preserved farmland. Instead, in the market outcome no acres will be preserved; the level of preserved farmland, QMKT, is equal to zero. That’s because farmers will set the marginal social cost of preservation—
Because farmers bear the entire cost of preservation but gain none of the benefits, an inefficiently low quantity of acres will be preserved in the market outcome.
A Pigouvian subsidy is a payment designed to encourage activities that yield external benefits.
This is clearly inefficient because at zero acres preserved, the marginal social benefit of preserving an acre of farmland is $20,000. So how can the economy be induced to produce QOPT acres of preserved farmland, the socially optimal level? The answer is a Pigouvian subsidy: a payment designed to encourage activities that yield external benefits. The optimal Pigouvian subsidy, as shown in Figure 16-4, is equal to the marginal social benefit of preserved farmland at the socially optimal level, QOPT —that is, $10,000 per acre.
So New Jersey voters are indeed implementing the right policy to raise their social welfare—
A technology spillover is an external benefit that results when knowledge spreads among individuals and firms.
In the overall U.S. economy, the most important single source of external benefits is the creation of knowledge. In high-
In technologically advanced countries such as the United States, Japan, the United Kingdom, Germany, France, and Israel, there is an ongoing exchange of people and ideas among private industries, major universities, and research institutes located in close proximity. The dynamic interplay that occurs in these research clusters spurs innovation and competition, theoretical advances, and practical applications.
One of the best known and most successful research clusters is the Research Triangle in North Carolina, anchored by Duke University and the University of North Carolina, several other universities and hospitals, and companies such as IBM, Pfizer, and Qualcomm. Ultimately, these areas of technology spillover increase the economy’s productivity and raise living standards.
But research clusters don’t appear out of thin air. Except in a few instances in which firms have funded basic research on a long-
The Impeccable Economic Logic of Early-
One of the most vexing problems facing any society is how to break what researchers call the “cycle of poverty”: children who grow up in disadvantaged socioeconomic circumstances are far more likely to remain trapped in poverty as adults, even after we account for differences in ability. They are more likely to be unemployed or underemployed, to engage in crime, and to suffer chronic health problems.
Early-
Another study by researchers at the University of Pittsburgh looked at early-
The observed external benefits to society of these programs are so large that the Brookings Institution predicts that providing high-
When there are positive externalities, or external benefits, a market economy, left to itself, will typically produce too little of the good or activity. The socially optimal quantity of the good or activity can be achieved by an optimal Pigouvian subsidy.
The most important example of external benefits in the economy is the creation of knowledge through technology spillover.
In 2013, the U.S. Department of Education spent almost $36 billion on college student aid. Explain why this can be an optimal policy to encourage the creation of knowledge.
In each of the following cases, determine whether an external cost or an external benefit is imposed and what an appropriate policy response would be.
Trees planted in urban areas improve air quality and lower summer temperatures.
Water-
Old computer monitors contain toxic materials that pollute the environment when improperly disposed of.
Solutions appear at back of book.