Competitive Markets—And Others

Early in this chapter, we defined a competitive market and explained that the supply and demand framework is a model of competitive markets. But we took a rain check on the question of why it matters whether or not a market is competitive. Now that we’ve seen how the supply and demand model works, we can offer some explanation.

To understand why competitive markets are different from other markets, compare the problems facing two individuals: a wheat farmer who must decide whether to grow more wheat and the president of a giant aluminum company—say, Alcoa—who must decide whether to produce more aluminum.

For the wheat farmer, the question is simply whether the extra wheat can be sold at a price high enough to justify the extra production cost. The farmer need not worry about whether producing more wheat will affect the price of the wheat he or she was already planning to grow. That’s because the wheat market is competitive. There are thousands of wheat farmers, and no one farmer’s decision will have any impact on the market price.

For the Alcoa executive, things are not that simple because the aluminum market is not competitive. There are only a few big producers, including Alcoa, and each of them is well aware that its actions do have a noticeable impact on the market price. This adds a whole new level of complexity to the decisions producers have to make. Alcoa can’t decide whether or not to produce more aluminum just by asking whether the additional product will sell for more than it costs to make. The company also has to ask whether producing more aluminum will drive down the market price and reduce its profit, its net gain from producing and selling its output.

When a market is competitive, individuals can base decisions on less complicated analyses than those used in a noncompetitive market. This in turn means that it’s easier for economists to build a model of a competitive market than of a noncompetitive market.

Don’t take this to mean that economic analysis has nothing to say about noncompetitive markets. On the contrary, economists can offer some very important insights into how other kinds of markets work. But those insights require other models, which we will learn about later on.

An Uber Way to Get a Ride

In a densely populated city like New York City, finding a taxi is a relatively easy task on most days—stand on a corner, put out your arm and, usually, before long an available cab stops to pick you up. And even before you step into the car you will know approximately how much it will cost to get to your destination, because taxi meter rates are set by city regulators and posted for riders.

But at times it is not so easy to find a taxi—on rainy days, during rush hour, and at crowded locations where many people are looking for a taxi at the same time. At such times, you could wait a very long while before finding an available cab. As you wait, you will probably notice empty taxis passing you by—drivers who have quit working for the day and are headed home or back to the garage. There will be drivers who might stop, but then won’t pick you up because they find your destination inconvenient. Moreover, there are times when it is simply impossible to hail a taxi—for example, during a snowstorm or on New Year’s Eve when the demand for taxis far exceeds the supply.

In 2009 two young entrepreneurs, Garrett Camp and Travis Kalanick, founded Uber, a company that they believe offers a better way to get a ride. Using a smartphone app, Uber serves as a clearinghouse connecting people who want a ride to drivers with cars who are registered with Uber. Confirm your location using the Uber app and you’ll be shown the available cars in your vicinity. Tap “book” and you receive a text saying your car—typically a spotless Lincoln Town Car—is on its way. At the end of your trip, fare plus tip are automatically deducted from your credit card. As of 2014 Uber operates in 70 cities around the world and booked more than $1 billion in rides in 2013.

Mark Avery/Zuma Wire/Alamy

Given that Uber provides personalized service and better quality cars, their fares are somewhat higher than regular taxi fares during normal driving days—a situation that customers seem happy with. However, the qualification during normal driving hours is an important one because at other times Uber’s rates fluctuate. When a lot of people are looking for a car—such as during a snowstorm or on New Year’s Eve—Uber uses what it calls surge pricing, setting the rate higher until everyone who wants a car at the going price can get one. So during a recent New York snowstorm, rides cost up to 8.25 times the standard price. Enraged, some of Uber’s customers have accused them of price gouging.

But according to Kalanick, the algorithm that Uber uses to determine the surge price is set to leave as few people as possible without a ride, and he’s just doing what is necessary to keep customers happy. As he explains, “We do not own cars nor do we employ drivers. Higher prices are required in order to get cars on the road and keep them on the road during the busiest times.” This explanation was confirmed by one Uber driver who said, “If I don’t have anything to do and see a surge price, I get out there.”

QUESTIONS FOR THOUGHT

  1. Question 3.6

    1aycOB4kbqyiDtcXEEGq1L3LKnfHeGRIL7GPpsXvXiGJHqLRy6ft/cSsfmNLS6tE4IasnIyu2bMTMOhuaqJeNrK3NwhWcgWQow8Z6wwj7gzSEsyO8ZDEkrHvmaeaVj10jtklHungCg9Zrua8
    Before Uber, how were prices set in the market for rides in New York City? Was it a competitive market?
  2. Question 3.7

    3+Aai14C87vcMSRnuIlxU1O/YLIlvITvOnZnU+e6HhNpvhEZnOO9MDvVaA+LdiaFR92Z0Zo7586aENd5c/H4o2tQRKv+J0MNUhBRhNtWGNEkHYabveUZdSPHbZxNKMxLflMXGo4MZJinskrv3ga4vx2Vq/TlD++bAkQ3dKwYyO+T8XcUnFbi6wRFdXF1AFAyuU385nrd+rDbjTeSK0P8s6ydTjkt4nrYwO8wLQ==
    What accounts for the fact that during good weather there are typically enough taxis for everyone who wants one, but during snowstorms there typically aren’t enough?
  3. Question 3.8

    KApzp1z0hTIw6IVsJliZ7ptv4iFu1FjhX7qDVMQmq2w7JVynodtfVdS3qG1nKWL3N33tHG9gaO4YDfPTEXV3mf1KY4Oq6WaKt55G12BrZFJXsA9tfqZL6m40ndyiSapit5T8057yitdEwzsGN18gB6HAMs4pm3Qb8tH7+Xe8Tt9CvuqM/8gbPaNhUqLd6oaw49IPo5XmdkMn1U7FF5GMss6VYLGGNHIMVjaFQpR0i4nab0kl10HyvVQO1WQ=
    How does Uber’s surge pricing solve the problem described in the previous question? Assess Kalanick’s claim that the price is set to leave as few people possible without a ride.