Taming the Business Cycle

Modern macroeconomics largely came into being as a response to the worst recession in history—the 43-month downturn that began in 1929 and continued into 1933, ushering in the Great Depression. The havoc wreaked by the 1929–1933 recession spurred economists to search both for understanding and for solutions: they wanted to know how such things could happen and how to prevent them.

As we explained earlier in this chapter, the work of John Maynard Keynes, published during the Great Depression, suggested that monetary and fiscal policies could be used to mitigate the effects of recessions, and to this day governments turn to Keynesian policies when recession strikes. Later work, notably that of another great macroeconomist, Milton Friedman, led to a consensus that it’s important to rein in booms as well as to fight slumps. So modern policy makers try to “smooth out” the business cycle. They haven’t been completely successful, as a look back at Figure 6-2 makes clear. It’s widely believed, however, that policy guided by macroeconomic analysis has helped make the economy more stable.

Although the business cycle is one of the main concerns of macroeconomics and historically played a crucial role in fostering the development of the field, macroeconomists are also concerned with other issues. We turn next to the question of long-run growth.

Slumps Across the Atlantic

This figure shows manufacturing production from 2007 to 2013 in two of the world’s biggest economies: the United States and the Euro Area, the group of European countries that share a common currency, the euro. As you can see, both economies suffered a severe downturn in 2008–2009, probably because banks in both economies had made many bad loans, and failures on one side of the Atlantic helped create a crisis of confidence on the other side as well.

More or less simultaneous recessions in different countries are, in fact, quite common. But that doesn’t mean that economies always or even usually move in lockstep. As you can see from the figure, both the Euro Area and the United States began to recover in mid-2009. In 2011, however, their paths diverged. The U.S. economy continued to recover steadily, although more slowly than most would have liked. The Euro Area, by contrast, entered a new recession in 2011, due to problems of excessive debt in some countries and a wrong turn in economic policy, discussed in Chapter 17.

What we learn from recent experience, then, is that the business cycle is to some extent an international phenomenon. But individual countries can diverge from each other for a variety of reasons, including policy differences and differences in the underlying structure of their economies.

Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

ECONOMICS in Action: Comparing Recessions

Comparing Recessions

The alternation of recessions and expansions seems to be an enduring feature of economic life. However, not all business cycles are created equal. In particular, some recessions have been much worse than others.

Let’s compare the two most recent U.S. recessions: the 2001 recession and the Great Recession of 2007–2009. These recessions differed in duration: the first lasted only eight months, the second more than twice as long. Even more important, however, they differed greatly in depth.

Two U.S. Recessions Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

In Figure 6-5 we compare the depth of the recessions by looking at what happened to industrial production over the months after the recession began. In each case, production is measured as a percentage of its level at the recession’s start. Thus the line for the 2007–2009 recession shows that industrial production eventually fell to about 85% of its initial level.

Clearly, the 2007–2009 recession hit the economy vastly harder than the 2001 recession. Indeed, by comparison to many recessions, the 2001 slump was very mild.

Of course, this was no consolation to the millions of American workers who lost their jobs, even in that mild recession.

Quick Review

  • The business cycle, the short-run alternation between recessions and expansions, is a major concern of modern macroeconomics.

  • The point at which expansion shifts to recession is a business-cycle peak. The point at which recession shifts to expansion is a business-cycle trough.

6-2

  1. Question 6.3

    Why do we talk about business cycles for the economy as a whole, rather than just talking about the ups and downs of particular industries?

  2. Question 6.4

    Describe who gets hurt in a recession, and how.

Solutions appear at back of book.