A good economic model can be a tremendous aid to understanding. In this module, we look at the production possibility frontier, a model that helps economists think about the trade-
You make a trade-
One of the important principles of economics we introduced in Module 1 was that resources are scarce. As a result, any economy—
Consider Boeing’s newest jet, the 787 Dreamliner. The plane, which took its historic first test flight in 2009, was the result of an aerodynamic revolution—
The production possibility frontier (PPF) illustrates the trade-
To think about the trade-
Suppose, for a moment, that the United States was a one-
Figure 2-1 shows a hypothetical production possibility frontier representing the trade-
There is a crucial distinction between points inside or on the production possibility curve (the shaded area) and outside the curve. If a production point lies inside or on the curve—
In Figure 2-1 the production possibility curve intersects the horizontal axis at 40 small jets. This means that if Boeing dedicated all its production capacity to making only small jets, it could produce 40 small jets per year. The production possibility curve intersects the vertical axis at 30 Dreamliners. This means that if Boeing dedicated all its production capacity to making Dreamliners, it could produce a maximum of 30 Dreamliners per year.
The figure also shows less extreme trade-
Thinking in terms of a production possibility frontier simplifies the complexities of reality. The real-
By simplifying reality, the production possibility frontier helps us understand some aspects of the real economy better than we could without the model: efficiency, opportunity cost, and economic growth.
An economy is efficient if there is no way to make anyone better off without making anyone else worse off.
The production possibility frontier is useful for illustrating the general economic concept of efficiency. An economy is efficient if there are no missed opportunities—
When an economy is using all of its resources efficiently, the only way one person can be made better off is by rearranging the use of resources in such a way that the change makes someone else worse off. So in our classroom example, if all larger classrooms or lecture halls were already fully occupied, we could say that the school was run in an efficient way; your classmates could be made better off only by making people in the larger classroom worse off—
Returning to our Boeing example, as long as Boeing operates on its production possibility curve, its production is efficient. At point A, 15 Dreamliners are the maximum quantity feasible given that Boeing has also committed to producing 20 small jets; at point B, 9 Dreamliners are the maximum number that can be made given the choice to produce 28 small jets; and so on.
But suppose for some reason that Boeing was operating at point C, making 20 small jets and 9 Dreamliners. In this case, it would not be operating efficiently and would therefore be inefficient: it could be producing more of both planes.
Another example of inefficiency in production occurs when people in an economy are involuntarily unemployed: they want to work but are unable to find jobs. When that happens, the economy is not efficient in production because it could produce more output if those people were employed. The production possibility frontier shows the amount that can possibly be produced if all resources are fully employed. In other words, changes in unemployment move the economy closer to, or further away from, the PPF. But the curve itself is determined by what would be possible if there were full employment in the economy. Greater unemployment is represented by points farther below the PPF—
Although the production possibility frontier helps clarify what it means for an economy to be efficient in production, it’s important to understand that efficiency in production is only part of what’s required for the economy as a whole to be efficient. Efficiency also requires that the economy allocate its resources so that consumers are as well off as possible. If an economy does this, we say that it is efficient in allocation.
To see why efficiency in allocation is as important as efficiency in production, notice that points A and B in Figure 2-1 both represent situations in which the economy is efficient in production, because in each case it can’t produce more of one good without producing less of the other. But these two situations may not be equally desirable. It may be more desirable to have more small jets and fewer Dreamliners than at point A; such as 28 small jets and 9 Dreamliners, corresponding to point B. In this case, point A is inefficient from the point of view of the economy as a whole: it is possible to move from point A to point B, and have some be made better off without making anyone else worse off.
This example shows that efficiency for the economy as a whole requires both efficiency in production and efficiency in allocation. To be efficient, an economy must produce as much of each good as it can, given the production of other goods, and it must also produce the mix of goods that people want to consume.
The production possibility frontier is also useful as a reminder that the true cost of any good isn’t the money it costs to buy, but what must be given up in order to get that good—
Is the opportunity cost of an extra small jet in terms of Dreamliners always the same, no matter how many small jets and Dreamliners are currently produced? In the example illustrated by Figure 2-1, the answer is yes. If Boeing increases its production of small jets from 28 to 40, the number of Dreamliners it produces falls from 9 to zero. So Boeing’s opportunity cost per additional small jet is of a Dreamliner, the same as it was when Boeing went from 20 small jets produced to 28. The fact that the opportunity cost is always the same number—
Moreover, as you might have already guessed, the slope of a straight-
Figure 2-2 illustrates a different assumption, a case in which Boeing faces increasing opportunity cost. Here, the more small jets it produces, the more costly it is to produce yet another small jet in terms of reduced production of a Dreamliner. For example, to go from producing zero small jets to producing 20, Boeing has to give up producing 5 Dreamliners. That is, the opportunity cost of those 20 small jets is 5 Dreamliners. But to increase its production of small jets to 40—
Although it’s often useful to work with the simple assumption that the production possibility curve is a straight line, economists believe that in reality, opportunity costs are typically increasing. When only a small amount of a good is produced, the opportunity cost of producing that good is relatively low because the economy needs to use only those resources that are especially well suited for its production. For example, if an economy grows only a small amount of corn, that corn can be grown in places where the soil and climate are perfect for growing corn but less suitable for growing anything else, such as wheat.
So growing that corn involves giving up only a small amount of potential wheat output. Once the economy grows a lot of corn, however, land that is well suited for wheat but isn’t so great for corn must be used to produce corn anyway. As a result, the additional corn production involves sacrificing considerably more wheat production. In other words, as more of a good is produced, its opportunity cost typically rises because well-
Finally, the production possibility frontier helps us understand what it means to talk about economic growth, which economists describe as creating a sustained rise in aggregate output. Economic growth is one of the fundamental features of the economy. But are we really justified in saying that the economy has grown over time? After all, although the U.S. economy produces more of many things than it did a century ago, it produces less of other things—
The answer, illustrated in Figure 2-3, is that economic growth means an expansion of the economy’s production possibilities: the economy can produce more of everything. In it, we assume again that our economy is only made up of Boeing, and therefore, our economy only produces two goods, Dreamliners and small jets. For example, if Boeing’s production is initially at point A (20 small jets and 25 Dreamliners) economic growth means that Boeing could move to point E (25 small jets and 30 Dreamliners). Point E lies outside the original curve, so in the production possibility frontier model, growth is shown as an outward shift of the curve.
Factors of production are resources used to produce goods and services.
What can lead the production possibility curve to shift outward? There are basically two sources of economic growth. One is an increase in the economy’s factors of production, the resources used to produce goods and services. Broadly speaking, the main factors of production are the resources land, labor, physical capital, and human capital. As you learned in Module 1, land is a resource supplied by nature; labor is the economy’s pool of workers; physical capital refers to created resources such as machines and buildings; and human capital refers to the educational achievements and skills of the labor force, which enhance its productivity.
Technology is the technical means for producing goods and services.
To see how adding to an economy’s factors of production leads to economic growth, suppose that Boeing builds another construction hangar that allows it to increase the number of planes—
The other source of economic growth is progress in technology, the technical means for the production of goods and services. Composite materials had been used in some parts of aircraft before the Boeing Dreamliner was developed. But Boeing engineers realized that there were large additional advantages to building a whole plane out of composites. The plane would be lighter, stronger, and have better aerodynamics than a plane built in the traditional way. It would therefore have longer range, be able to carry more people, and use less fuel, in addition to being able to maintain higher cabin pressure. So in a real sense Boeing’s innovation—
But even if, for some reason, Boeing chooses to produce either fewer Dreamliners or fewer small jets than before, we would still say that this economy has grown, because it could have produced more of everything. At the same time, if an economy’s production possibility curve shifts inward, the economy has become smaller. This could happen if the economy loses resources or technology (for example, if it experiences war or a natural disaster).
The production possibility frontier is a very simplified model of an economy. Yet it teaches us important lessons about real-
Solutions appear at the back of the book.
Check Your Understanding
True or false? Explain your answer.
a. An increase in the amount of resources available to Boeing for use in producing Dreamliners and small jets does not change its production possibility curve.
b. A technological change that allows Boeing to build more small jets for any amount of Dreamliners built results in a change in its production possibility curve.
c. The production possibility frontier is useful because it illustrates how much of one good an economy must give up to get more of another good regardless of whether resources are being used efficiently.
Multiple-
Refer to the accompanying graph to answer the following questions.
Critical-
Assume that an economy can choose between producing food and producing shelter at a constant opportunity cost. Graph a correctly labeled production possibility curve for the economy. On your graph: