1.2 Module 14: Categories of Unemployment

Lightspring/Shutterstock

WHAT YOU WILL LEARN

  • The three different types of unemployment and their causes
  • The factors that determine the natural rate of unemployment

Fast economic growth tends to reduce the unemployment rate. So how low can the unemployment rate go? You might be tempted to say zero, but that isn’t feasible. Over the past half-century, the national unemployment rate has never dropped below 2.9%.

How can there be so much unemployment even when many businesses are having a hard time finding workers? To answer this question, we need to examine the nature of labor markets and why they normally lead to substantial measured unemployment even when jobs are plentiful. Our starting point is the observation that even in the best of times, jobs are constantly being created and destroyed.

Job Creation and Job Destruction

Even during good times, most Americans know someone who has lost his or her job. The U.S. unemployment rate in July 2007 was only 4.7%, relatively low by historical standards, yet in that month there were 4.5 million “job separations”—terminations of employment that occurred because a worker was either fired or quit voluntarily.

There are many reasons for such job loss. One is structural change in the economy: industries rise and fall as new technologies emerge and consumers’ tastes change. For example, employment in high-tech industries such as telecommunications surged in the late 1990s but slumped severely after 2000. However, structural change also brings the creation of new jobs: since 2000, the number of jobs in the American health care sector has surged as new medical technologies have emerged and the aging of the population has increased the demand for medical care.

Poor management or bad luck at a company also leads to job loss for employees. For example, in 2005 General Motors announced plans to eliminate 30,000 jobs after several years of lagging sales, even as Japanese companies such as Toyota announced plans to open new plants in North America to meet growing demand for their cars.

Continual job creation and destruction are a feature of modern economies, making a naturally occurring amount of unemployment inevitable. Within this naturally occurring amount, there are two types of unemployment—frictional and structural.

Frictional Unemployment

Workers who spend time looking for employment are engaged in job search.

Workers who lose a job involuntarily due to job destruction often choose not to take the first new job offered. For example, suppose a skilled programmer, laid off because her software company’s product line was unsuccessful, sees a help-wanted ad for clerical work online. She might respond to the ad and get the job—but that would be foolish. Instead, she should take the time to look for a job that takes advantage of her skills and pays accordingly. In addition, individual workers are constantly leaving jobs voluntarily, typically for personal reasons—family moves, dissatisfaction, and better job prospects elsewhere.

Frictional unemployment is unemployment due to the time workers spend in job search.

Economists say that workers who spend time looking for employment are engaged in job search. If all workers and all jobs were alike, job search wouldn’t be necessary; if information about jobs and workers were perfect, job search would be very quick. In practice, however, it’s normal for a worker who loses a job, or a young worker seeking a first job, to spend at least a few weeks searching.

© The New Yorker Collection 2009 Christopher Weyant from cartoonbank.com. All Rights Reserved.

Frictional unemployment is unemployment due to the time workers spend in job search. A certain amount of frictional unemployment is inevitable due to the constant process of economic change. Even in 2007, a year of low unemployment, there were 62 million “job separations,” in which workers left or lost their jobs. Total employment grew because these separations were more than offset by more than 63 million hires. Inevitably, some of the workers who left or lost their jobs spent at least some time unemployed, as did some of the workers newly entering the labor force.

Figure 14-1 shows the 2007 average monthly flows of workers among three states: employed, unemployed, and not in the labor force. What the figure suggests is how much churning is constantly taking place in the labor market. An inevitable consequence of that churning is a significant number of workers who haven’t yet found their next job—that is, frictional unemployment.

Even in 2007, a low-unemployment year, large numbers of workers moved into and out of both employment and unemployment each month. On average, each month in 2007, 1.781 million unemployed became employed, and 1.929 million employed became unemployed.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

A limited amount of frictional unemployment is relatively harmless and may even be a good thing. The economy is more productive if workers take the time to find jobs that are well matched to their skills and workers who are unemployed for a brief period while searching for the right job don’t experience great hardship. In fact, when there is a low unemployment rate, periods of unemployment tend to be quite short, suggesting that much of the unemployment is frictional.

Figure 14-2 shows the composition of unemployment for all of 2007, when the unemployment rate was only 4.6%. Thirty-six percent of the unemployed had been unemployed for less than 5 weeks, and only 33% had been unemployed for 15 or more weeks. Only about one in six unemployed workers were considered to be “long-term unemployed”—unemployed for 27 or more weeks.

In years when the unemployment rate is low, most unemployed workers are unemployed for only a short period. In 2007, a year of low unemployment, 36% of the unemployed had been unemployed for less than 5 weeks and 67% for less than 15 weeks. The short duration of unemployment for most workers suggests that most unemployment in 2007 was frictional.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

In periods of higher unemployment, however, workers tend to be jobless for longer periods of time, suggesting that a smaller share of unemployment is frictional. By 2010, the fraction of unemployed workers considered “long-term unemployed” had jumped to 43%.

Structural Unemployment

In structural unemployment, more people are seeking jobs in a particular labor market than there are jobs available at the current wage rate.

Frictional unemployment exists even when the number of people seeking jobs is equal to the number of jobs being offered—that is, the existence of frictional unemployment doesn’t mean that there is a surplus of labor. Sometimes, however, there is a persistent surplus of job-seekers in a particular labor market, even when the economy is performing well. There may be more workers with a particular skill than there are jobs available using that skill, or there may be more workers in a particular geographic region than there are jobs available in that region. Structural unemployment is unemployment that results when there are more people seeking jobs in a labor market than there are jobs available at the current wage rate.

The supply and demand model tells us that the price of a good, service, or factor of production tends to move toward an equilibrium level that matches the quantity supplied with the quantity demanded. This is equally true, in general, of labor markets.

Figure 14-3 shows a typical market for labor. The labor demand curve indicates that when the price of labor—the wage rate—increases, employers demand less labor. The labor supply curve indicates that when the price of labor increases, more workers are willing to supply labor at the prevailing wage rate. These two forces coincide to lead to an equilibrium wage rate for any given type of labor in a particular location. That equilibrium wage rate is shown as WE.

When the government sets a minimum wage, WF, that exceeds the market equilibrium wage rate, WE, the number of workers, QS, who would like to work at that minimum wage is greater than the number of workers, QD, demanded at that wage rate. This surplus of labor is considered structural unemployment.

Even at the equilibrium wage rate, WE, there will still be some frictional unemployment. That’s because there will always be some workers engaged in job search even when the number of jobs available is equal to the number of workers seeking jobs. But there wouldn’t be any structural unemployment in this labor market. Structural unemployment occurs when the wage rate is, for some reason, persistently above WE. Several factors can lead to a wage rate in excess of WE, the most important being minimum wages, labor unions, efficiency wages, the side effects of government policies, and mismatches between employees and employers.

Minimum WagesA minimum wage is a government-mandated floor on the price of labor. In the United States, the national minimum wage in 2013 was $7.25 an hour. For many American workers, the minimum wage is irrelevant; the market equilibrium wage for these workers is well above this price floor. But for less-skilled workers, the minimum wage may be binding—it affects the wages that people are actually paid and can lead to structural unemployment. In countries that have higher minimum wages, the range of workers for whom the minimum wage is binding is larger.

Figure 14-3 shows the effect of a binding minimum wage. In this market, there is a legal floor on wages, WF, which is above the equilibrium wage rate, WE. This leads to a persistent surplus in the labor market: the quantity of labor supplied, QS, is larger than the quantity demanded, QD. In other words, more people want to work than can find jobs at the minimum wage, leading to structural unemployment.

Given that minimum wages—that is, binding minimum wages—generally lead to structural unemployment, you might wonder why governments impose them. The rationale is to help ensure that people who work can earn enough income to afford at least a minimally comfortable lifestyle. However, this may come at a cost, because it may eliminate employment opportunities for some workers who would have willingly worked for lower wages. As illustrated in Figure 14-3, not only are there more sellers of labor than there are buyers, but there are also fewer people working at a minimum wage (QD) than there would have been with no minimum wage at all (QE).

Although economists broadly agree that a high minimum wage has the employment-reducing effects shown in Figure 14-3, there is some question about whether this is a good description of how the minimum wage actually works in the United States. The minimum wage in the United States is quite low compared with that in other wealthy countries. For three decades, from the 1970s to the mid-2000s, the U.S. minimum wage was so low that it was not binding for the vast majority of workers.

Minimum-wage workers advocating for a living wage, one that is high enough to maintain a normal standard of living.
Marmaduke St. John/Alamy

In addition, some researchers have produced evidence that increases in the minimum wage actually lead to higher employment when, as was the case in the United States at one time, the minimum wage is low compared to average wages. They argue that firms employing low-skilled workers sometimes restrict their hiring in order to keep wages low and that, as a result, the minimum wage can sometimes be increased without any loss of jobs. Most economists, however, agree that a sufficiently high minimum wage does lead to structural unemployment.

Labor UnionsThe actions of labor unions can have effects similar to those of minimum wages, leading to structural unemployment. By bargaining collectively for all of a firm’s workers, unions can win higher wages from employers than workers would have obtained by bargaining individually. This process, known as collective bargaining, is intended to tip the scales of bargaining power more toward workers and away from employers.

Labor unions exercise bargaining power by threatening firms with a labor strike, a collective refusal to work. The threat of a strike can have serious consequences for firms. In such cases, workers acting collectively can exercise more power than they could if they acted individually.

When workers have greater bargaining power, they tend to demand and push the wage that workers receive above the equilibrium wage. Consequently, there are more people willing to work at the wage being paid than there are jobs available, leading to structural unemployment. In the United States, however, because of a low level of unionization, the amount of unemployment generated by union demands is likely to be very small.

Efficiency wages are wages that employers set above the equilibrium wage rate as an incentive for better employee performance.

Efficiency WagesActions by firms may also contribute to structural unemployment. Firms may choose to pay efficiency wages—wages that employers set above the equilibrium wage rate as an incentive for their workers to deliver better performance.

Employers may feel the need for such incentives for several reasons. For example, employers often have difficulty observing directly how hard an employee works. They can, however, elicit more work effort by paying above-market wages: employees receiving these higher wages are more likely to work harder to ensure that they aren’t fired, which would cause them to lose their higher wages.

When many firms pay efficiency wages, the result is a pool of workers who want jobs but can’t find them. So the use of efficiency wages by firms leads to structural unemployment.

Side Effects of Government PoliciesIn addition, government policies designed to help workers who lose their jobs can lead to structural unemployment as an unintended side effect. Most economically advanced countries provide benefits to laid-off workers as a way to tide them over until they find a new job. In the United States, these benefits typically replace only a small fraction of a worker’s income and expire after 26 weeks. This was extended in some cases to 99 weeks during the period of high unemployment that began in 2009. Although the extension expired at the end of 2013, at the time of this writing, Congress was considering whether to once again extend the benefits.

In other countries, particularly in Europe, benefits are more generous and last longer. The drawback to this generosity is that it reduces the incentive to quickly find a new job, and by keeping more people searching for longer, the benefits increase structural and frictional unemployment. Generous unemployment benefits in some European countries are widely believed to be one of the main causes of “Eurosclerosis,” the persistent high unemployment that afflicts a number of European economies.

Mismatches Between Employees and EmployersIt takes time for workers and firms to adjust to shifts in the economy. The result can be a mismatch between what employees have to offer and what employers are looking for. A skills mismatch is one form; for example, in the aftermath of the housing bust of 2009, there were more construction workers looking for jobs than jobs available. Another form is geographic, as in Michigan, which has had a long-standing surplus of workers since its auto industry went into decline.

Until the mismatch is resolved through a fall in wages for surplus workers that is big enough to induce retraining or relocation, there will be structural unemployment.

The Natural Rate of Unemployment

Because some frictional unemployment is inevitable and because many economies also suffer from structural unemployment, a certain amount of unemployment is normal, or “natural.” Actual unemployment fluctuates around this normal level.

The natural rate of unemployment is the unemployment rate that arises from the effects of frictional plus structural unemployment.

Cyclical unemployment is the deviation of the actual rate of unemployment from the natural rate.

The natural rate of unemployment is the normal unemployment rate around which the actual unemployment rate fluctuates. It is the rate of unemployment that arises from the effects of frictional plus structural unemployment. Cyclical unemployment is the deviation of the actual rate of unemployment from the natural rate; that is, it is the difference between the actual and natural rates of unemployment. As the name suggests, cyclical unemployment is the share of unemployment that arises from the business cycle. Later we’ll see that government policy cannot keep the unemployment rate persistently below the natural rate without leading to accelerating inflation.

We can summarize the relationships between the various types of unemployment as follows:

Perhaps because of its name, people often imagine that the natural rate of unemployment is a constant that doesn’t change over time and can’t be affected by policy. Neither proposition is true. Let’s take a moment to stress two facts: the natural rate of unemployment changes over time, and it can be affected by economic policies.

Changes in the Natural Rate of Unemployment

Private-sector economists and government agencies need estimates of the natural rate of unemployment to make forecasts and conduct policy analyses. Almost all these estimates show that the U.S. natural rate rises and falls over time. For example, the Congressional Budget Office, the independent agency that conducts budget and economic analyses for Congress, believes that the U.S. natural rate of unemployment was 5.3% in 1950, rose to 6.3% by the end of the 1970s, but has as fallen to 5.5% today. European countries have experienced even larger swings in their natural rates of unemployment.

What causes the natural rate of unemployment to change? The most important factors are

Changes in Labor Force CharacteristicsIn December 2013 the overall rate of unemployment in the United States was 6.7%. Young workers, however, had much higher unemployment rates: 20.2% for teenagers and 11.1% for workers aged 20 to 24. Workers aged 25 to 54 had an unemployment rate of only 5.8%.

Luna Vandoorne/Shutterstock

In general, unemployment rates tend to be lower for experienced than for inexperienced workers. Because experienced workers tend to stay in a given job longer, they have lower frictional unemployment. Also, because older workers are more likely than young workers to be family breadwinners, they have a stronger incentive to find and keep jobs.

One reason the natural rate of unemployment rose during the 1970s was a large rise in the number of new workers—children of the post–World War II baby boom entered the labor force, as did a rising percentage of married women.

As Figure 14-4 shows, both the percentage of the labor force less than 25 years old and the percentage of women in the labor force surged in the 1970s. By the end of the 1990s, however, the share of women in the labor force had leveled off and the percentage of workers under 25 had fallen sharply. As a result, the labor force as a whole is more experienced today than it was in the 1970s, one likely reason that the natural rate of unemployment is lower today than in the 1970s.

In the 1970s the percentage of the labor force consisting of women rose rapidly, as did the percentage under age 25. These changes reflected the entry of large numbers of women into the paid labor force for the first time and the fact that baby boomers were reaching working age. The natural rate of unemployment may have risen because many of these workers were relatively inexperienced. Today, the labor force is much more experienced, which is one possible reason the natural rate has fallen since the 1970s.
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.

Changes in Labor Market InstitutionsAs we pointed out earlier, unions that negotiate wages above the equilibrium level can be a source of structural unemployment. Some economists believe that strong labor unions are one reason for the high natural rate of unemployment in Europe. In the United States, a sharp fall in union membership after 1980 may have been one reason the natural rate of unemployment fell between the 1970s and the 1990s.

Other institutional changes may also have been at work. For example, some labor economists believe that temporary employment agencies, which have proliferated in recent years, have reduced frictional unemployment by helping match workers to jobs. And, of course, job-search websites such as Monster.com may have reduced frictional unemployment.

YinYang/Getty Images

Technological change, coupled with labor market institutions, can also affect the natural rate of unemployment. Technological change probably leads to an increase in the demand for skilled workers who are familiar with the relevant technology and a reduction in the demand for unskilled workers. Economic theory predicts that wages should increase for skilled workers and decrease for unskilled workers. But if wages for unskilled workers cannot go down—say, due to a binding minimum wage—increased structural unemployment, and therefore a higher natural rate of unemployment, will result.

Changes in Government PoliciesA high minimum wage can cause structural unemployment and generous unemployment benefits can increase both structural and frictional unemployment. So government policies intended to help workers can have the undesirable side effect of raising the natural rate of unemployment.

Some government policies, however, may reduce the natural rate. Two examples are job training and employment subsidies. Job-training programs are supposed to provide unemployed workers with skills that widen the range of jobs they can perform. Employment subsidies are payments either to workers or to employers that provide a financial incentive to accept or offer jobs.

!world_eia!NATURAL UNEMPLOYMENT AROUND THE OECD

The Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) is an association of relatively wealthy countries, in Europe and North America but also including Japan, Korea, New Zealand, and Australia. Among other activities, the OECD collects data on unemployment rates for member nations. Figure 14-5 shows average unemployment, which is a rough estimate of the natural rate of unemployment, for select OECD members, from 2000–2012. The purple bar in the middle shows the average across all the OECD countries.

Source: OECD.

The U.S. natural rate of unemployment appears to be somewhat below average; those of many European countries (including the major economies of Germany, Italy, and France) are above average. Many economists think that persistently high European unemployment rates are the result of government policies, such as high minimum wages and generous unemployment benefits, which discourage employers from offering jobs and discourage workers from accepting jobs, leading to high rates of structural unemployment.

Module 14 Review

Solutions appear at the back of the book.

Check Your Understanding

  1. Explain the following.

    • a. Frictional unemployment always exists.

    • b. Frictional unemployment accounts for a larger share of total unemployment when the unemployment rate is low.

  2. Why does collective bargaining have the same general effect on unemployment as a minimum wage? Illustrate your answer with a diagram.

  3. Suppose the United States dramatically increases benefits for unemployed workers. Explain what will happen to the natural rate of unemployment.

Multiple-Choice Questions

  1. Question

    Eztoe3JVMUChUtZvpE1MF6SsavRsneTXM/QdtVb5XUPutIgSdc3y+AwRKWZqERmaYT+OCtVUVPxaKOVXtY7VCnvGa6HTsG8dA5xTOU4lDQC+wRoyiGFtakoKm+K5yUUKdaPr6biB201jG3vZI4qM0cIbIw88psZJDmBsrtshWY9t701jJTXa07y1ZlswVsqJvXuF7tyFpgRjYuxJgK0C69958AgaLwTTBFb8ds2XqXHa1tuGtnnd/gkeVCmPIU4hKH522vo5FEcqH/gBikncJDteTpytSDZB
  2. Question

    V3q2oJsfsyH676d3VOeOpyiPCwrH4Uay6bFH53o1TtDLnSHEz8Bh6oTPfbtFsu30Tua+kedVbosHh8ejU7LHGY+KvbfwT4qsJ7alOGnt3sYJn4MdmV9iZYarQHDumee12RTDCk2BRTqGTNQUkIYife4drfpWNV6bLDVbOyTDyPq98JuL6hrjEDtpU/nVO7Gax0tj2uFLELG2EneK
  3. Question

    VbXviPQCB/JdqdS7QJlKAK8HWzHx8kybw3td059Ot0D6vzJxcvq3iO89bmbuhSz+qLODSrHP01I+VvqCmKlQbg3s55xBn+1eGwtGfX9mNQPEqer3o0UtZr9NXbTNA0YuqKRiXGNTDUrX/mceaVL+0i52KhMYiSy4k+BZD0THKK+LQZFlay2H8nPsRmuWyknaDbT4pmQwoa7aFiHEuvCvXPdGB++J4hpvoinabiuOjcMGpQuNRv/GtjMVUnQkE7t1+r6o5M1t3+M4JD49dbobvrUOVm0vA7ER2q4jPsbpMX+R74qfKf3nLFk2dhfnSVT32D5T4jGGDpFnZmEe03b5y8/vquzr+YNDTdeR37MVA0g=
  4. Question

    Rt9svBFJMb0f+5AtSoUNnV/EOQx19bdprSIlmBcgTGwqSFel9z/e9ARK0hp9Wo1BpKsV7Z9UuqG4HZ2paKJfrywslo+sh7phjFob/zY8wJfE1PklkplYqaok7Q12n29DVy5ZgevT2r2yTdmxL5vnyBydu+FZAA8RDGe66BFe4YsTigsN1goOUy/uesiY4Qy7bbjSeNYmxoTavAPjdn8TjAooJ8Ar5nan+tq7W+P94X4gPUqTF6YWgJe6cw0MROYZ1HWEdO1FigCYVz4hBkNkjuxz7gDc7ZYg19J2ZOimwU6UeckgCZieORBGsoxcLB8YFtg2kM/siUTh4NuhxsTCcBUO4cyF4WHEcNAf6xGz7Gkra+UUTRv4cGQa6zHoB8XnakQXUcQ1RE5p6sPavXltYmzeLdfdxIWyYA0hrnEdgheXz3uWreFSSg==
  5. Question

    pW2sdKVh+HA21eaDsH3C8WFJddKrHjyWSpufzQcukB72YOVx9cNClUb5hPJktpZddX9mS5e4UKE2y5digTMpbYmHFLlPd8OEsIcIcXkn2DURjHLijc6pa9f3wMH/4sBr4dkBR4+j1DK0kNEofr+zL0b1v6nfuphmDfr0EXtxba8kOY7p96d8GA4v9FRUDT80nq9iEV0H0qBAWzYxP9BoxB7l/17O9WqeWQao9+V6UJoBtVWptK36O8K/vTz5LUXFLFoX2+oqSD4wn33NEXBz4DehLoVcY33SRnyi30CJbJ3zceqS/ytnJC4SogSipGQDZOj/6RcNXy77L84Gn1PcOlE0NQLgBW0ezJeaeVDQ67vmpgbwCJ3cjaFPvPuXl/GYw5xM02TPzM4or5LlspKGivqKrW5GvJmwLHT/SpGx/wgsjMXFPZB9QlgKB14=

Critical-Thinking Question

If the number of unemployed people who find jobs is greater than the number of employed people who lose their jobs in a given month then the unemployment rate will decrease. Is this statement true or false? Explain.