Before 1970 there were no rules governing the amount of sulfur dioxide that power plants in the United States could emit—
In this module we’ll look at the three types of policies governments typically use to deal with pollution:
We’ll also see how economic analysis has been used to improve those policies.
Because the economy, and life itself, depends on a viable environment, external costs that threaten the environment—
Environmental standards are rules that protect the environment by specifying limits or actions for producers and consumers.
How does a country protect its environment? At present the main policy tools are environmental standards, rules that protect the environment by specifying actions by producers and consumers. A familiar example is the law that requires almost all vehicles to have catalytic converters, which reduce the emission of chemicals that can cause smog and lead to health problems. Other rules require communities to treat their sewage, factories to limit their pollution emissions, and homes to be painted with lead-
Environmental standards came into widespread use in the 1960s and 1970s with considerable success. Since the United States passed the Clean Air Act in 1970, for example, the emission of air pollutants has fallen by more than a third, even though the population has grown by a third and the size of the economy has more than doubled. Even in Los Angeles, still famous for its smog, the air has improved dramatically: in 1976 ozone levels in the South Coast Air Basin exceeded federal standards on 194 days; in 2010, on only 7 days. Improvements have continued in 2013.
Despite these successes, economists believe that when regulators can control a polluter’s emissions directly, there are more efficient ways than environmental standards to deal with pollution. By using methods grounded in economic analysis, society can achieve a cleaner environment at lower cost.
Most current environmental standards are inflexible and don’t allow reductions in pollution to be achieved at the lowest possible cost. For example, two power plants—
How does economic theory suggest that pollution should be controlled? We’ll examine two approaches: taxes and tradable permits. As we’ll see, either approach can achieve the efficient outcome at the minimum feasible cost.
An emissions tax is a tax that depends on the amount of pollution a firm produces.
One way to deal with pollution directly is to charge polluters an emissions tax. Emissions taxes depend on the amount of pollution a firm produces. For example, power plants might be charged $200 for every ton of sulfur dioxide they emit.
Consider the socially optimal quantity of pollution, QOPT, shown in Figure 37-1. At that quantity of pollution, the marginal social benefit and the marginal social cost of an additional ton of emissions are equal at $200. But in the absence of government intervention, power companies have no incentive to limit pollution to the socially optimal quantity QOPT; instead, they will push pollution up to the quantity QMKT, at which the marginal social benefit is zero.
It’s now easy to see how an emissions tax can solve the problem. If power companies are required to pay a tax of $200 per ton of emissions, they face a marginal cost of $200 per ton and have an incentive to reduce emissions to QOPT, the socially optimal quantity. This illustrates a general result: an emissions tax equal to the marginal social cost at the socially optimal quantity of pollution induces polluters to internalize the externality—
Why is an emissions tax an efficient way (that is, a cost-
Figure 37-2 shows a hypothetical industry consisting of only two plants, plant A and plant B. We’ll assume that plant A uses newer technology than plant B and so has a lower cost of reducing pollution. Reflecting this difference in costs, plant A’s marginal benefit of pollution curve, MBA, lies below plant B’s marginal benefit of pollution curve, MBB. Because it is more costly for plant B to reduce its pollution at any output quantity, an additional ton of pollution is worth more to plant B than to plant A.
In the absence of government action, polluters will pollute until the marginal social benefit of an additional unit of emissions is equal to zero. Recall that the marginal social benefit of pollution is the cost savings, at the margin, to polluters of an additional unit of pollution. As a result, without government intervention each plant will pollute until its own marginal benefit of pollution is equal to zero. This corresponds to an emissions quantity of 600 tons each for plants A and B—
Now suppose that the government decides that overall pollution from this industry should be cut in half, from 1,200 tons to 600 tons. Panel (a) of Figure 37-2 shows how this might be achieved with an environmental standard that requires each plant to cut its emissions in half, from 600 to 300 tons. The standard has the desired effect of reducing overall emissions from 1,200 to 600 tons but accomplishes it in an inefficient way. As you can see from panel (a), the environmental standard leads plant A to produce at point SA, where its marginal benefit of pollution is $150, but plant B produces at point SB, where its marginal benefit of pollution is twice as high, $300.
This difference in marginal benefits between the two plants tells us that the same quantity of pollution can be achieved at lower total cost by allowing plant B to pollute more than 300 tons but inducing plant A to pollute less. In fact, the efficient way to reduce pollution is to ensure that at the industry-
We can see from panel (b) how an emissions tax achieves exactly that result. Suppose both plant A and plant B pay an emissions tax of $200 per ton so that the marginal cost of an additional ton of emissions to each plant is now $200 rather than zero. As a result, plant A produces at TA and plant B produces at TB. So plant A reduces its pollution more than it would under an inflexible environmental standard, cutting its emissions from 600 to 200 tons; meanwhile, plant B reduces its pollution less, going from 600 to 400 tons. In the end, total pollution—
Taxes designed to reduce external costs are known as Pigouvian taxes.
The term emissions tax may convey the misleading impression that taxes are a solution to only one kind of external cost, pollution. In fact, taxes can be used to discourage any activity that generates negative externalities, such as driving during rush hour or operating a noisy bar in a residential area. In general, taxes designed to reduce external costs are known as Pigouvian taxes, after the economist A.C. Pigou, who emphasized their usefulness in a classic 1920 book, The Economics of Welfare. Look again at Figure 37-1. In our example, the optimal Pigouvian tax is $200; this corresponds to the marginal social cost of pollution at the optimal output quantity, QOPT.
Are there any problems with emissions taxes? The main concern is that in practice government officials usually aren’t sure at what level the tax should be set. If they set the tax too low, improvement in the environment will be inadequate; if they set it too high, emissions will be reduced by more than is efficient. This uncertainty cannot be eliminated, but the nature of the risks can be changed by using an alternative strategy, issuing tradable emissions permits.
Tradable emissions permits are licenses to emit limited quantities of pollutants that can be bought and sold by polluters.
Tradable emissions permits are licenses to emit limited quantities of pollutants that can be bought and sold by polluters. They are usually issued to polluting firms according to some formula reflecting their history. For example, each power plant might be issued permits equal to 50% of its emissions before the system went into effect. The more important point, however, is that these permits are tradable. Firms with differing costs of reducing pollution can now engage in mutually beneficial transactions: those that find it easier to reduce pollution will sell some of their permits to those that find it more difficult.
In other words, firms will use transactions in permits to reallocate pollution reduction among themselves, so that in the end those with the lowest cost will reduce their pollution the most and those with the highest cost will reduce their pollution the least. Assume that the government issues 300 permits each to plant A and plant B, where one permit allows the emission of one ton of pollution. Under a system of tradable emissions permits, commonly known as a cap and trade program, plant A will find it profitable to sell 100 of its 300 government-
Just like emissions taxes, tradable permits provide polluters with an incentive to take the marginal social cost of pollution into account. To see why, suppose that the market price of a permit to emit one ton of sulfur dioxide is $200. Then every plant has an incentive to limit its emissions of sulfur dioxide to the point where its marginal benefit of emitting another ton of pollution is $200. This is obvious for plants that buy rights to pollute: if a plant must pay $200 for the right to emit an additional ton of sulfur dioxide, it faces the same incentives as a plant facing an emissions tax of $200 per ton.
But it’s equally true for plants that have more permits than they plan to use: by not emitting a ton of sulfur dioxide, a plant frees up a permit that it can sell for $200, so the opportunity cost of a ton of emissions to the plant’s owner is $200.
In short, tradable emissions permits have the same cost-
It’s important to realize that emissions taxes and tradable permits do more than induce polluting industries to reduce their output. Unlike rigid environmental standards, emissions taxes and tradable permits provide incentives to create and use technology that emits less pollution—
The main problem with tradable emissions permits is the flip-
After first relying on environmental standards, the U.S. government has turned to a system of tradable permits to control acid rain. Current proposals would extend the system to other major sources of pollution. And in 2005 the European Union created an emissions-
The tradable emissions permit systems for both acid rain in the United States and greenhouse gases in the European Union are examples of cap and trade systems: the government sets a cap (a maximum amount of pollutant that can be emitted), issues tradable emissions permits, and enforces a yearly rule that a polluter must hold a number of permits equal to the amount of pollutant emitted. The goal is to set the cap low enough to generate environmental benefits, while giving polluters flexibility in meeting environmental standards and motivating them to adopt new technologies that will lower the cost of reducing pollution.
In 1994 the United States began a cap and trade system for the sulfur dioxide emissions that cause acid rain by issuing permits to power plants based on their historical consumption of coal. Thanks to the system, air pollutants in the United States decreased by more than 40% from 1990 to 2008, and 2010 acid rain levels dropped to approximately 50% of their 1980 levels and they continue to drop.
Economists who have analyzed the sulfur dioxide cap and trade system point to another reason for its success: it would have been a lot more expensive—
The EU cap and trade scheme, covering all 28 member nations of the European Union (plus Iceland, Liechtenstein, and Norway), is the world’s only mandatory trading scheme for greenhouse gases. It is scheduled to achieve a 21% reduction in greenhouse gases by 2020 compared to 2005 levels.
Despite all this good news, however, cap and trade systems are not silver bullets for the world’s pollution problems for these reasons:
New Jersey is the most densely populated state in the country, lying along the northeastern corridor, an area of almost continuous development stretching from Washington, D.C., to Boston. Yet a drive through New Jersey reveals a surprising feature: acre upon acre of farmland, growing everything from corn to pumpkins to the famous Jersey tomatoes. This situation is no accident: starting in 1961, New Jerseyans have voted in a series of measures that subsidize farmers to permanently preserve their farmland rather than sell it to developers.
Why have New Jersey citizens voted to raise their own taxes to subsidize the preservation of farmland? Because they believe that preserved farmland in an already heavily developed state provides external benefits, such as natural beauty, access to fresh food, and the conservation of wild bird populations. In addition, preservation alleviates the external costs that come with more development, such as pressure on roads, water supplies, and municipal services—
In this section we’ll explore the topics of external benefits and positive externalities. They are, in many ways, the mirror images of external costs and negative externalities. Left on its own, the market will produce too little of a good (in this case, preserved New Jersey farmland) that confers external benefits on others. But society as a whole is better off when policies are adopted that increase the supply of such a good.
Preserved farmland yields both benefits and costs to society. In the absence of government intervention, the farmer who wants to sell his land incurs all the costs of preservation—
Figure 37-3 illustrates society’s problem. The marginal social cost of preserved farmland, shown by the MSC curve, is the additional cost imposed on society by an additional acre of such farmland. This represents the forgone profits that would have accrued to farmers if they had sold their land. The line is upward-
The MSB curve represents the marginal social benefit of preserved farmland. It is the additional benefit that accrues to society—
The market alone will not provide QOPT acres of preserved farmland. Instead, in the market outcome no acres will be preserved; the level of preserved farmland, QMKT, is equal to zero. That’s because farmers will set the marginal social cost of preservation—
A Pigouvian subsidy is a payment designed to encourage activities that yield external benefits.
This is clearly inefficient because at zero acres preserved, the marginal social benefit of preserving an acre of farmland is $20,000. So how can the economy be induced to produce QOPT acres of preserved farmland, the socially optimal level? The answer is a Pigouvian subsidy: a payment designed to encourage activities that yield external benefits. The optimal Pigouvian subsidy, as shown in Figure 37-3, is equal to the marginal social benefit of preserved farmland at the socially optimal level, QOPT—that is, $10,000 per acre.
So New Jersey voters are indeed implementing the right policy to raise their social welfare—
A technology spillover is an external benefit that results when knowledge spreads among individuals and firms.
In the overall U.S. economy, the most important single source of external benefits is the creation of knowledge. In high-
In technologically advanced countries such as the United States, Japan, the United Kingdom, Germany, France, and Israel, there is an ongoing exchange of people and ideas among private industries, major universities, and research institutes located in close proximity. The dynamic interplay that occurs in these research clusters spurs innovation and competition, theoretical advances, and practical applications. (See the Business Case at the end of the section for more on research clusters.) Ultimately, these areas of technology spillover increase the economy’s productivity and raise living standards.
But research clusters don’t appear out of thin air. Except in a few instances in which firms have funded basic research on a long-
Unlike positive externalities, network externalities have no inherently favorable or adverse effect on society at large. They do, however, affect other users of the associated good or service. Consider Facebook again: if you were the only user of Facebook, what would it be worth to you? The answer, of course, is nothing. Facebook derives its value only from the fact that other people also use it. And the more people who use Facebook, the more valuable it is to you.
A good is subject to a network externality when the value of the good to an individual is greater when other people also use the good.
A network externality exists when the value of a good or service to an individual is greater when a large number of other people also use the good or service. Although network externalities are common in technology-
For all network externalities, the value of the good or service is derived entirely from its ability to link many people possessing the same good or service. As a result, the marginal benefit of the good or service to any one individual depends on the number of other individuals who use it.
Although most network externalities involve methods of communication—
Even your choice of a car is influenced by a form of network externality. Most people would be reluctant to switch to a car that runs on natural gas because fueling the car would be difficult: very few gas stations offer natural gas. And the reason service stations do not offer natural gas is, of course, that few people drive anything other than gasoline-
A good is subject to positive feedback when success breeds greater success and failure breeds further failure.
When a good or service is subject to a network externality, it exhibits positive feedback: if large numbers of people buy it, other people become more likely to buy it, too. If people don’t buy the good or service, others become less likely to buy it. So both success and failure tend to be self-
Solutions appear at the back of the book.
Check Your Understanding
1. Some opponents of tradable emissions permits object to them on the grounds that polluters that sell their permits benefit monetarily from their involvement in polluting the environment. Assess this argument.
2. In 2010, the U.S. Department of Education spent almost $35 billion on college student aid. Explain why this can be an optimal policy to encourage the creation of knowledge.
3. For each of the following cases, explain whether an external cost or an external benefit is created and identify an appropriate policy response.
a. Trees planted in urban areas improve air quality and lower summer temperatures.
b. Water-
c. Old computer monitors contain toxic materials that pollute the environment when improperly disposed of.
Multiple-
Critical-
The use of plastic water bottles creates a negative externality by increasing pollution and the amount of material sent into a landfill. Suppose we imposed a tax of $0.50 for each water bottle purchased in the United States. Would that be an efficient Pigouvian tax? Why or why not?