Now that we have learned about the firm’s production function, we can use that knowledge to develop its cost curves. To see how a firm’s production function is related to its cost curves, let’s turn once again to George and Martha’s farm.
Once George and Martha know their production function, they know the relationship between inputs of labor and land and output of wheat. But if they want to maximize their profits, they need to translate this knowledge into information about the relationship between the quantity of output and cost. Let’s see how they can do this.
A fixed cost is a cost that does not depend on the quantity of output produced. It is the cost of the fixed input.
To translate information about a firm’s production function into information about its cost, we need to know how much the firm must pay for its inputs. We will assume that George and Martha face either an explicit or an implicit cost of $400 for the use of the land. As we learned previously, it is irrelevant whether George and Martha must rent the land for $400 from someone else or whether they own the land themselves and forgo earning $400 from renting it to someone else. Either way, they pay an opportunity cost of $400 by using the land to grow wheat. Moreover, since the land is a fixed input for which George and Martha pay $400 whether they grow one bushel of wheat or one hundred, its cost is a fixed cost, denoted by FC—a cost that does not depend on the quantity of output produced. In business, a fixed cost is often referred to as an overhead cost.
A variable cost is a cost that depends on the quantity of output produced. It is the cost of the variable input.
The total cost of producing a given quantity of output is the sum of the fixed cost and the variable cost of producing that quantity of output.
We also assume that George and Martha must pay each worker $200. Using their production function, George and Martha know that the number of workers they must hire depends on the amount of wheat they intend to produce. So the cost of labor, which is equal to the number of workers multiplied by $200, is a variable cost, denoted by VC—a cost that depends on the quantity of output produced. Adding the fixed cost and the variable cost of a given quantity of output gives the total cost, or TC, of that quantity of output. We can express the relationship among fixed cost, variable cost, and total cost as an equation:
or
TC = FC + VC
The table in Figure 22-1 shows how total cost is calculated for George and Martha’s farm. The second column shows the number of workers employed, L. The third column shows the corresponding level of output, Q, taken from the table in Figure 22-1. The fourth column shows the variable cost, VC, equal to the number of workers multiplied by $200. The fifth column shows the fixed cost, FC, which is $400 regardless of the quantity of wheat produced. The sixth column shows the total cost of output, TC, which is the variable cost plus the fixed cost.
The total cost curve shows how total cost depends on the quantity of output.
The first column labels each row of the table with a letter, from A to I. These labels will be helpful in understanding our next step: drawing the total cost curve, a curve that shows how total cost depends on the quantity of output.
George and Martha’s total cost curve is shown in the diagram in Figure 22-1, where the horizontal axis measures the quantity of output in bushels of wheat and the vertical axis measures total cost in dollars. Each point on the curve corresponds to one row of the table in Figure 22-1. For example, point A shows the situation when 0 workers are employed: output is 0, and total cost is equal to fixed cost, $400. Similarly, point B shows the situation when 1 worker is employed: output is 19 bushels, and total cost is $600, equal to the sum of $400 in fixed cost and $200 in variable cost.
Like the total product curve, the total cost curve slopes upward: due to the increasing variable cost, the more output produced, the higher the farm’s total cost. But unlike the total product curve, which gets flatter as employment rises, the total cost curve gets steeper. That is, the slope of the total cost curve is greater as the amount of output produced increases. As we will soon see, the steepening of the total cost curve is also due to diminishing returns to the variable input. Before we can see why, we must first look at the relationships among several useful measures of cost.
We’ve just learned how to derive a firm’s total cost curve from its production function. Our next step is to take a deeper look at total cost by deriving two extremely useful measures: marginal cost and average cost. As we’ll see, these two measures of the cost of production have a somewhat surprising relationship to each other. Moreover, they will prove to be vitally important in later modules, where we will use them to analyze the firm’s output decision and the market supply curve.
Marginal cost is the added cost of doing something one more time. In the context of production, marginal cost is the change in total cost generated by producing one more unit of output. We’ve already seen that marginal product is easiest to calculate if data on output are available in increments of one unit of input. Similarly, marginal cost is easiest to calculate if data on total cost are available in increments of one unit of output because the increase in total cost for each unit is clear. When the data come in less convenient increments, it’s still possible to calculate marginal cost over each interval. But for the sake of simplicity, let’s work with an example in which the data come in convenient one-
Selena’s Gourmet Salsas produces bottled salsa; Table 22-1 shows how its costs per day depend on the number of cases of salsa it produces per day. The firm has a fixed cost of $108 per day, shown in the second column, which is the daily rental cost of its food-
The significance of the slope of the total cost curve is shown by the fifth column of Table 22-1, which indicates marginal cost—
or
As in the case of marginal product, marginal cost is equal to “rise” (the increase in total cost) divided by “run” (the increase in the quantity of output). So just as marginal product is equal to the slope of the total product curve, marginal cost is equal to the slope of the total cost curve.
Now we can understand why the total cost curve gets steeper as it increases from left to right: as you can see in Table 22-1, marginal cost at Selena’s Gourmet Salsas rises as output increases. And because marginal cost equals the slope of the total cost curve, a higher marginal cost means a steeper slope. Panel (b) of Figure 22-2 shows the marginal cost curve corresponding to the data in Table 22-1. Notice that we plot the marginal cost for increasing output from 0 to 1 case of salsa halfway between 0 and 1, the marginal cost for increasing output from 1 to 2 cases of salsa halfway between 1 and 2, and so on.
Why does the marginal cost curve slope upward? Because there are diminishing returns to inputs in this example. As output increases, the marginal product of the variable input declines. This implies that more and more of the variable input must be used to produce each additional unit of output as the amount of output already produced rises. And since each unit of the variable input must be paid for, the additional cost per additional unit of output also rises.
Recall that the flattening of the total product curve is also due to diminishing returns: if the quantities of other inputs are fixed, the marginal product of an input falls as more of that input is used. The flattening of the total product curve as output increases and the steepening of the total cost curve as output increases are just flip-
In addition to total cost and marginal cost, it’s useful to calculate average total cost, often simply called average cost. The average total cost is total cost divided by the quantity of output produced; that is, it is equal to total cost per unit of output. If we let ATC denote average total cost, the equation looks like this:
Average total cost, often referred to simply as average cost, is total cost divided by quantity of output produced.
Average total cost is important because it tells the producer how much the average or typical unit of output costs to produce. Marginal cost, meanwhile, tells the producer how much one more unit of output costs to produce. Although they may look very similar, these two measures of cost typically differ. And confusion between them is a major source of error in economics, both in the classroom and in real life.
Table 22-2 uses data from Selena’s Gourmet Salsas to calculate average total cost. For example, the total cost of producing 4 cases of salsa is $300, consisting of $108 in fixed cost and $192 in variable cost (from Table 22-1 So the average total cost of producing 4 cases of salsa is $300/4 = $75. You can see from Table 22-2 that as the quantity of output increases, average total cost first falls, then rises.
Quantity of salsa Q (cases) | Total cost TC | Average total cost of case ATC = TC/Q | Average fixed cost of case AFC = FC/Q | Average variable cost of case AVC = VC/Q |
---|---|---|---|---|
1 | $120 | $120.00 | $108.00 | $12.00 |
2 | 156 | 78.00 | 54.00 | 24.00 |
3 | 216 | 72.00 | 36.00 | 36.00 |
4 | 300 | 75.00 | 27.00 | 48.00 |
5 | 408 | 81.60 | 21.60 | 60.00 |
6 | 540 | 90.00 | 18.00 | 72.00 |
7 | 696 | 99.43 | 15.43 | 84.00 |
8 | 876 | 109.50 | 13.50 | 96.00 |
9 | 1,080 | 120.00 | 12.00 | 108.00 |
10 | 1,308 | 130.80 | 10.80 | 120.00 |
A U-
Figure 22-3 plots that data to yield the average total cost curve, which shows how average total cost depends on output. As before, cost in dollars is measured on the vertical axis and quantity of output is measured on the horizontal axis. The average total cost curve has a distinctive U shape that corresponds to how average total cost first falls and then rises as output increases. Economists believe that such U-
Average fixed cost is the fixed cost per unit of output.
Average variable cost is the variable cost per unit of output.
To help our understanding of why the average total cost curve is U-
Average total cost is the sum of average fixed cost and average variable cost; it has a U shape because these components move in opposite directions as output rises.
Average fixed cost falls as more output is produced because the numerator (the fixed cost) is a fixed number but the denominator (the quantity of output) increases as more is produced. Another way to think about this relationship is that, as more output is produced, the fixed cost is spread over more units of output; the end result is that the fixed cost per unit of output—the average fixed cost—
You can see this effect in the fourth column of Table 22-2: average fixed cost drops continuously as output increases.
Average variable cost, however, rises as output increases. As we’ve seen, this reflects diminishing returns to the variable input: each additional unit of output adds more to variable cost than the previous unit because increasing amounts of the variable input are required to make another unit.
So increasing output has two opposing effects on average total cost—
At low levels of output, the spreading effect is very powerful because even small increases in output cause large reductions in average fixed cost. So at low levels of output, the spreading effect dominates the diminishing returns effect and causes the average total cost curve to slope downward.
But when output is large, average fixed cost is already quite small, so increasing output further has only a very small spreading effect. Diminishing returns, however, usually grow increasingly important as output rises. As a result, when output is large, the diminishing returns effect dominates the spreading effect, causing the average total cost curve to slope upward.
At the bottom of the U-
Figure 22-4 brings together in a single picture the four other cost curves that we have derived from the total cost curve for Selena’s Gourmet Salsas: the marginal cost curve (MC), the average total cost curve (ATC), the average variable cost curve (AVC), and the average fixed cost curve (AFC). All are based on the information in Tables 22-1 and 22-2. As before, cost is measured on the vertical axis and the quantity of output is measured on the horizontal axis.
Let’s take a moment to note some features of the various cost curves. First of all, marginal cost slopes upward—
Finally, notice that the marginal cost curve intersects the average total cost curve from below, crossing it at its lowest point, point M in Figure 22-4. This last feature is our next subject of study.
The minimum-
For a U-
In Figure 22-4, the bottom of the U is at the level of output at which the marginal cost curve crosses the average total cost curve from below. Is this an accident? No—
To understand these principles, think about how your grade in one course—
Similarly, if marginal cost—
But if your grade in physics is more than the average of your previous grades, this new grade raises your GPA. Similarly, if marginal cost is greater than average total cost, producing that extra unit raises average total cost. This is illustrated by the movement from B1 to B2 in Figure 22-5, where the marginal cost, MCH, is higher than average total cost. So any quantity of output at which marginal cost is greater than average total cost must be on the upward-
Finally, if a new grade is exactly equal to your previous GPA, the additional grade neither raises nor lowers that average—
Housing developments have traditionally been considered as American as apple pie. With our abundant supply of undeveloped land, real estate developers have long found it profitable to buy big parcels of land, build a large number of homes, and create entire new communities. But what is profitable for developers is not necessarily good for the existing residents.
Of late, real estate developers have encountered increasingly stiff resistance from local residents because of the additional costs—
In the United States, a large percentage of the funding for local services comes from taxes paid by local homeowners. In a sense, the local township authority uses those taxes to “produce” municipal services for the town. The overall level of property taxes is set to reflect the costs of providing those services. The highest service cost by far, in most communities, is the cost of public education.
The local tax rate that new homeowners pay on their new homes is the same as what existing homeowners pay on their older homes. That tax rate reflects the current total cost of services, and the taxes that an average homeowner pays reflect the average total cost of providing services to a household. The average total cost of providing services is based on the town’s use of existing facilities, such as the existing school buildings, the existing number of teachers, the existing fleet of school buses, and so on.
But when a large development of homes is constructed, those facilities are no longer adequate: new schools must be built, new teachers hired, and so on. The quantity of output increases. So the marginal cost of providing municipal services per household associated with a new, large-
A recent study in Massachusetts estimated that a $250,000 new home with one school-
Up to this point, we have emphasized the importance of diminishing returns, which lead to a marginal product curve that always slopes downward and a marginal cost curve that always slopes upward. In practice, however, economists believe that marginal cost curves often slope downward as a firm increases its production from zero up to some low level, sloping upward only at higher levels of production: marginal cost curves look like the curve labeled MC in Figure 22-6.
This initial downward slope occurs because a firm often finds that, when it starts with only a very small number of workers, employing more workers and expanding output allows its workers to specialize in various tasks. This, in turn, lowers the firm’s marginal cost as it expands output. For example, one individual producing salsa would have to perform all the tasks involved: selecting and preparing the ingredients, mixing the salsa, bottling and labeling it, packing it into cases, and so on.
As more workers are employed, they can divide the tasks, with each worker specializing in one or a few aspects of salsa-
However, as Figure 22-6 also shows, the key features we saw from the example of Selena’s Gourmet Salsas remain true: the average total cost curve is U-
Solutions appear at the back of the book.
Check Your Understanding
1. Alicia’s Apple Pies is a roadside business. Alicia must pay $9.00 in rent each day. In addition, it costs her $1.00 to produce the first pie of the day, and each subsequent pie costs 50% more to produce than the one before. For example, the second pie costs $1.00 × 1.5 = $1.50 to produce, and so on.
a. Calculate Alicia’s marginal cost, variable cost, average fixed cost, average variable cost, and average total cost as her daily pie output rises from 0 to 6. (Hint: The variable cost of two pies is just the marginal cost of the first pie, plus the marginal cost of the second, and so on.)
b. Indicate the range of pies for which the spreading effect dominates and the range for which the diminishing returns effect dominates.
c. What is Alicia’s minimum-
Multiple-
5. On the basis of the data in the table, what is the marginal cost of the third unit of output?
Q | VC | TC |
---|---|---|
0 | $0 | $40 |
1 | 20 | 60 |
2 | 50 | 90 |
3 | 90 | 130 |
4 | 140 | 180 |
5 | 200 | 240 |
Critical-
Draw a correctly labeled graph showing a firm with an upward sloping MC curve and typically shaped ATC, AVC, and AFC curves.