An irrational decision maker chooses an option that leaves him or her worse off than choosing another available option.
Sometimes, though, instead of being rational, people are irrational—they make choices that leave them worse off in terms of economic payoff and other considerations like fairness than if they had chosen another available option. Is there anything systematic that economists and psychologists can say about economically irrational behavior? Yes, because most people are irrational in predictable ways. People’s irrational behavior typically stems from six mistakes they make when thinking about economic decisions. The mistakes are listed in Table 9-8, and we will discuss each in turn.
1. Misperceiving opportunity costs |
2. Being overconfident |
3. Having unrealistic expectations about future behavior |
4. Counting dollars unequally |
5. Being loss- |
6. Having a bias toward the status quo |
TABLE 9-
Misperceptions of Opportunity Costs As we discussed at the beginning of this chapter, people tend to ignore nonmonetary opportunity costs—
Overconfidence It’s a function of ego: we tend to think we know more than we actually do. And even if alerted to how widespread overconfidence is, people tend to think that it’s someone else’s problem, not theirs. (Certainly not yours or mine!)
For example, a 1994 study asked students to estimate how long it would take them to complete their thesis “if everything went as well as it possibly could” and “if everything went as poorly as it possibly could.” The results: the typical student thought it would take him or her 33.9 days to finish, with an average estimate of 27.4 days if everything went well and 48.6 days if everything went poorly. In fact, the average time it took to complete a thesis was much longer, 55.5 days. Students were, on average, from 14% to 102% more confident than they should have been about the time it would take to complete their thesis.
Dan Ariely, a professor of psychology and behavioral economics, likes to do experiments with his students that help him explore the nature of irrationality. In his book Predictably Irrational, Ariely describes an experiment that gets to the heart of procrastination and ways to address it.
At the time, Ariely was teaching the same subject matter to three different classes, but he gave each class different assignment schedules. The grade in all three classes was based on three equally weighted papers.
Students in the first class were required to choose their own personal deadlines for submitting each paper. Once set, the deadlines could not be changed. Late papers would be penalized at the rate of 1% of the grade for each day late. Papers could be turned in early without penalty but also without any advantage, since Ariely would not grade papers until the end of the semester.
Students in the second class could turn in the three papers whenever they wanted, with no preset deadlines, as long as it was before the end of the term. Again, there would be no benefit for early submission.
Students in the third class faced what Ariely called the “dictatorial treatment.” He established three hard deadlines at the fourth, eighth, and twelfth weeks.
So which classes do you think achieved the best and the worst grades? As it turned out, the class with the least flexible deadlines—
Ariely learned two simple things about overconfidence from these results. First—
But the biggest revelation came from the class that set its own deadlines. The majority of those students spaced their deadlines far apart and got grades as good as those of the students under the dictatorial treatment. Some, however, did not space their deadlines far enough apart, and a few did not space them out at all. These last two groups did less well, putting the average of the entire class below the average of the class with the least flexibility. As Ariely notes, without well-
This experiment provides two important insights:
People who acknowledge their tendency to procrastinate are more likely to use tools for committing to a path of action.
Providing those tools allows people to make themselves better off.
If you have a problem with procrastination, hard deadlines, as irksome as they may be, are truly for your own good.
As you can see in the following For Inquiring Minds, overconfidence can cause problems with meeting deadlines. But it can cause far more trouble by having a strong adverse effect on people’s financial health. Overconfidence often persuades people that they are in better financial shape than they actually are. It can also lead to bad investment and spending decisions. For example, nonprofessional investors who engage in a lot of speculative investing—
Unrealistic Expectations About Future Behavior Another form of overconfidence is being overly optimistic about your future behavior: tomorrow you’ll study, tomorrow you’ll give up ice cream, tomorrow you’ll spend less and save more, and so on. Of course, as we all know, when tomorrow arrives, it’s still just as hard to study or give up something that you like as it is right now.
Strategies that keep a person on the straight-
Mental accounting is the habit of mentally assigning dollars to different accounts so that some dollars are worth more than others.
Counting Dollars Unequally If you tend to spend more when you pay with a credit card than when you pay with cash, particularly if you tend to splurge, then you are very likely engaging in mental accounting. This is the habit of mentally assigning dollars to different accounts, making some dollars worth more than others.
By spending more with a credit card, you are in effect treating dollars in your wallet as more valuable than dollars on your credit card balance, although in reality they count equally in your budget.
Credit card overuse is the most recognizable form of mental accounting. However, there are other forms as well, such as splurging after receiving a windfall, like an unexpected inheritance, or overspending at sales, buying something that seemed like a great bargain that you later regretted. It’s the failure to understand that, regardless of the form it comes in, a dollar is a dollar.
Loss aversion is an oversensitivity to loss, leading to unwillingness to recognize a loss and move on.
Loss Aversion Loss aversion is an oversensitivity to loss, leading to an unwillingness to recognize a loss and move on. In fact, in the lingo of the financial markets, “selling discipline”—being able and willing to quickly acknowledge when a stock you’ve bought is a loser and sell it—
Many investors, though, are reluctant to acknowledge that they’ve lost money on a stock and won’t make it back. Although it’s rational to sell the stock at that point and redeploy the remaining funds, most people find it so painful to admit a loss that they avoid selling for much longer than they should. According to Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, most people feel the misery of losing $100 about twice as keenly as they feel the pleasure of gaining $100.
Loss aversion can help explain why sunk costs are so hard to ignore: ignoring a sunk cost means recognizing that the money you spent is unrecoverable and therefore lost.
The status quo bias is the tendency to avoid making a decision and sticking with the status quo.
Status Quo Bias Another irrational behavior is status quo bias, the tendency to avoid making a decision altogether. A well-
If everyone behaved rationally, then the proportion of employees enrolled in 401(k) accounts at opt-
Why do people exhibit status quo bias? Some claim it’s a form of “decision paralysis”: when given many options, people find it harder to make a decision. Others claim it’s due to loss aversion and the fear of regret, to thinking that “if I do nothing, then I won’t have to regret my choice.” Irrational, yes. But not altogether surprising. However, rational people know that, in the end, the act of not making a choice is still a choice.