An “either–
“Either- |
“How much” decisions |
---|---|
Tide or Cheer? |
How many days before you do your laundry? |
Buy a car or not? |
How many miles do you go before an oil change in your car? |
An order of nachos or a sandwich? |
How many jalapenos on your nachos? |
Run your own business or work for someone else? |
How many workers should you hire in your company? |
Prescribe drug A or drug B for your patients? |
How much should a patient take of a drug that generates side effects? |
Graduate school or not? |
How many hours to study? |
TABLE 9-
According to the principle of “either–
In making economic decisions, as we have already emphasized, it is vitally important to calculate opportunity costs correctly. The best way to make an “either–
Let’s examine Ashley’s dilemma from a different angle to understand how this principle works. If she continues with advertising and goes to work immediately, the value today of her total lifetime earnings is $57,000 (the value today of her earnings over the next two years) + $500,000 (the value today of her total lifetime earnings thereafter) = $557,000. If she gets her teaching degree instead and works as a teacher, the value today of her total lifetime earnings is $600,000 (value today of her lifetime earnings after two years in school) − $40,000 (tuition) − $4,000 (interest payments) = $556,000. The economic profit from continuing in advertising versus becoming a teacher is $557,000 − $556,000 = $1,000.
ON JUNE 6, 1944, ALLIED SOLDIERS stormed the beaches of Normandy, beginning the liberation of France from German rule. Long before the assault, however, Allied generals had to make a crucial decision: where would the soldiers land?
They had to make an “either–
Thirty years earlier, at the beginning of World War I, German generals had to make a different kind of decision. They, too, planned to invade France, in this case via land, and had decided to mount that invasion through Belgium. The decision they had to make was not an “either–
So Allied generals made the right “either–
So the right choice for Ashley is to begin work in advertising immediately, which gives her an economic profit of $1,000, rather than become a teacher, which would give her an economic profit of −$1,000. In other words, by becoming a teacher she loses the $1,000 economic profit she would have gained by working in advertising immediately.
In making “either–
WHY ARE THERE ONLY TWO CHOICES?
In “either–
Yes, it does. That’s because any choice between three (or more) alternatives can always be boiled down to a series of choices between two alternatives. Here’s an illustration using three alternative activities: A, B, or C. (Remember that this is an “either–
Let’s say you begin by considering A versus B: in this comparison, A has a positive economic profit but B yields an economic loss. At this point, you should discard B as a viable choice because A will always be superior to B. The next step is to compare A to C: in this comparison, C has a positive economic profit but A yields an economic loss. You can now discard A because C will always be superior to A. You are now done: since A is better than B, and C is better than A, C is the correct choice.
In addition, businesses run by the owner (an entrepreneur) often fail to calculate the opportunity cost of the owner’s time in running the business. In that way, small businesses often underestimate their opportunity costs and overestimate their economic profit of staying in business.
Are we implying that the hundreds of thousands who have chosen to go back to school rather than find work in recent years are misguided? Not necessarily. As we mentioned before, the poor job market has greatly diminished the opportunity cost of forgone wages for many students, making continuing their education the optimal choice for them.
The following Economics in Action illustrates just how important it is in real life to understand the difference between accounting profit and economic profit.
Farming in the Shadow of Suburbia
Beyond the sprawling suburbs, most of New England is covered by dense forest. But this is not the forest primeval: if you hike through the woods, you encounter many stone walls, relics of the region’s agricultural past when stone walls enclosed fields and pastures. In 1880, more than half of New England’s land was farmed; by 2013, the amount was down to 10%.
The remaining farms of New England are mainly located close to large metropolitan areas. There farmers get high prices for their produce from city dwellers who are willing to pay a premium for locally grown, extremely fresh fruits and vegetables.
But now even these farms are under economic pressure caused by a rise in the implicit cost of farming close to a metropolitan area. As metropolitan areas have expanded during the last two decades, farmers increasingly ask themselves whether they could do better by selling their land to property developers.
In 2013, the average value of an acre of farmland in the United States as a whole was $2,900; in Rhode Island, the most densely populated of the New England states, the average was $11,800. The Federal Reserve Bank of Boston has noted that “high land prices put intense pressure on the region’s farms to generate incomes that are substantial enough to justify keeping the land in agriculture.”
The important point is that the pressure is intense even if the farmer owns the land because the land is a form of capital used to run the business. So maintaining the land as a farm instead of selling it to a developer constitutes a large implicit cost of capital.
A fact provided by the U.S. Department of Agriculture (USDA) helps us put a dollar figure on the portion of the implicit cost of capital due to development pressure for some Rhode Island farms. In 2004, a USDA program designed to prevent development of Rhode Island farmland by paying owners for the “development rights” to their land paid an average of $4,949 per acre for those rights alone. By 2013, the amount had risen to more than $11,800.
About two-
All costs are opportunity costs. They can be divided into explicit costs and implicit costs.
An activity’s accounting profit is not necessarily equal to its economic profit.
Due to the implicit cost of capital—the opportunity cost of using self-
The principle of “either–
Karma and Don run a furniture-
Supplies such as paint stripper, varnish, polish, sandpaper, and so on
Basement space that has been converted into a workroom
Wages paid to a part-
A van that they inherited and use only for transporting furniture
The job at a larger furniture restorer that Karma gave up in order to run the business
Assume that Ashley has a third alternative to consider: entering a two-
Suppose you have three alternatives—
Solutions appear at back of book.