So far, we have seen how growth in the money supply causes inflation. With inflation as a consequence, what would ever induce a central bank to increase the money supply substantially? Here we examine one answer to this question.
Let’s start with an indisputable fact: all governments spend money. Some of this spending is to buy goods and services (such as roads and police), and some is to provide transfer payments (for the poor and elderly, for example). A government can finance its spending in three ways. First, it can raise revenue through taxes, such as personal and corporate income taxes. Second, it can borrow from the public by selling government bonds. Third, it can print money.
The revenue raised by the printing of money is called seigniorage. The term comes from seigneur, the French word for “feudal lord.” In the Middle Ages, the lord had the exclusive right on his manor to coin money. Today this right belongs to the central government, and it is one source of revenue.
When the government prints money to finance expenditure, it increases the money supply. The increase in the money supply, in turn, causes inflation. Printing money to raise revenue is like imposing an inflation tax.
At first it may not be obvious that inflation can be viewed as a tax. After all, no one receives a bill for this tax—
The amount of revenue raised by printing money varies from country to country. In the United States, the amount has been small: seigniorage has usually accounted for less than 3 percent of government revenue. In Italy and Greece, seigniorage has often been more than 10 percent of government revenue.2 In countries experiencing hyperinflation, seigniorage is often the government’s chief source of revenue—
Paying for the American Revolution
Although seigniorage has not been a major source of revenue for the U.S. government in recent history, the situation was very different two and a half centuries ago. Beginning in 1775, the Continental Congress needed to find a way to finance the Revolution, but it had limited ability to raise revenue through taxation. It therefore relied on the printing of fiat money to help pay for the war.
The Continental Congress’s reliance on seigniorage increased over time. New issues of continental currency were about $6 million in 1775, $19 million in 1776, and $13 million in 1777. This amount increased to $63 million in 1778 and $125 million in 1779.
114
Not surprisingly, this rapid growth in the money supply led to massive inflation. At the end of the war, the price of gold measured in continental dollars was more than 100 times its level of only a few years earlier. The large quantity of the continental currency made the continental dollar nearly worthless. This experience also gave birth to a once-
When the new nation won its independence, there was a natural skepticism about fiat money. Upon the recommendation of the first secretary of the Treasury, Alexander Hamilton, Congress passed the Mint Act of 1792, which established gold and silver as the basis for a new system of commodity money.