At the same time that cottage industry began to infringe on the livelihoods of urban artisans, new Enlightenment ideals called into question the very existence of the guild system. Eighteenth-
In keeping with his fear of political oppression and with the “system of natural liberty” that he championed, Smith argued that government should limit itself to “only three duties”: it should provide a defense against foreign invasion, maintain civil order with courts and police protection, and sponsor certain indispensable public works and institutions that could never adequately profit private investors. He believed that the pursuit of self-
However, Smith did not advocate unbridled capitalism. Unlike many disgruntled merchant capitalists, he applauded the modest rise in real wages of British workers in the eighteenth century, stating: “No society can surely be flourishing and happy, of which the far greater part of the members are poor and miserable.” Smith also acknowledged that employers were “always and everywhere in a sort of tacit, but constant and uniform combination, not to raise the wages of labor above their actual rate” and sometimes entered “into particular combinations to sink the wages even below this rate.” While he celebrated the rise in productivity allowed by the division of labor, he also acknowledged its demoralizing effects on workers and called for government intervention to raise workers’ living standards.9
Many educated people in France, including government officials, shared Smith’s ideas. In 1774, the reform-
We wish to abolish these arbitrary institutions, which do not allow the poor man to earn his living; which reject a sex whose weakness has given it more needs and fewer resources . . . ; which destroy emulation and industry and nullify the talents of those whose circumstances have excluded them from membership of a guild; which deprive the state and the arts of all the knowledge brought to them by foreigners; which retard the progress of these arts . . . ; [and which] burden industry with an oppressive tax, which bears heavily on the people.10
Vociferous popular protest against these measures led to Turgot’s disgrace shortly afterward and the cancellation of his reforms, but the legislators of the French Revolution (see Chapter 19) returned to a liberal economic agenda in 1789. The National Assembly definitively abolished guilds in 1791. Other European countries followed suit more slowly, with guilds surviving in central Europe and Italy into the second half of the nineteenth century. By the middle of the nineteenth century economic liberalism was championed by most European governments and elites.
Some artisans welcomed the deregulation espoused by Smith and Turgot, but many continued to uphold the ideals of the guilds. In the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, skilled artisans across Europe espoused the values of high-