7.1 The Economics of Taxes: A Preliminary View

An excise tax is a per unit tax on sales of a good or service.

To understand the economics of taxes, it’s helpful to look at a simple type of tax known as an excise tax—a tax charged on each unit of a good or service that is sold. Most tax revenue in Canada comes from other kinds of taxes, which we’ll describe later in this chapter. But excise taxes are common. For example, there are excise taxes on gasoline, cigarettes, and fuel-inefficient vehicles or ones with air conditioning. Many local governments impose excise taxes on services such as hotel room rentals. The lessons we’ll learn from studying excise taxes apply to other, more complex taxes as well.

The Effect of an Excise Tax on Quantities and Prices

Suppose that the supply and demand for hotel rooms in the city of Potterville are as shown in Figure 7-1. We’ll make the simplifying assumption that all hotel rooms are the same. In the absence of taxes, the equilibrium price of a room is $80 per night and the equilibrium quantity of hotel rooms rented is 10 000 per night.

Now suppose that Potterville’s government imposes an excise tax of $40 per night on hotel rooms—that is, every time a room is rented for the night, the owner of the hotel must pay the city $40. For example, if a customer pays $80, $40 is collected as a tax, leaving the hotel owner with only $40. As a result, hotel owners are less willing to supply rooms at any given price.

What does this imply about the supply curve for hotel rooms in Potterville? To answer this question, we must compare the incentives of hotel owners pre-tax (before the tax is levied) to their incentives post-tax (after the tax is levied).

From Figure 7-1 we know that pre-tax, hotel owners are willing to supply 5000 rooms per night at a price of $60 per room. But after the $40 tax per room is levied, they are willing to supply the same amount, 5000 rooms, only if they receive $100 per room—$60 for themselves plus $40 paid to the city as tax. In other words, in order for hotel owners to be willing to supply the same quantity post-tax as they would have pre-tax, they must receive an additional $40 per room, the amount of the tax. This implies that the post-tax supply curve shifts up by the amount of the tax compared to the pre-tax supply curve. At every quantity supplied, the supply price—the price that producers must receive to produce a given quantity—has increased by $40.

Figure7-1The Supply and Demand for Hotel Rooms in Potterville In the absence of taxes, the equilibrium price (PE) of hotel rooms is $80 a night, and the equilibrium number (QE) of rooms rented is 10 000 per night, as shown by point E. The supply curve, S, shows the quantity supplied at any given price, pre-tax. At a price of $60 a night, hotel owners are willing to supply 5000 rooms, point B. But post-tax, hotel owners are willing to supply the same quantity only at a price of $100: $60 for themselves plus $40 paid to the city as tax.

The upward shift of the supply curve caused by the tax is shown in Figure 7-2, where T is the amount of tax, S1 is the pre-tax supply curve, and S2 = S1 + T is the post-tax supply curve. As you can see, the market equilibrium moves from E, at the equilibrium price of PE = $80 per room and 10 000 rooms rented each night, to A, at a market price of PC = $100 per room and only 5000 rooms rented each night. A is, of course, on both the demand curve D and the new supply curve S2. In this case, $100 is the demand price (PC) of 5000 rooms—but in effect hotel owners receive only $60 (PP), when you account for the fact that they have to collect and remit the $40 tax. From the point of view of hotel owners, it is as if they were on their original supply curve at point B.

Figure7-2An Excise Tax Imposed on Hotel Owners A $40 per room tax imposed on hotel owners shifts the supply curve from S1 to S2, an upward shift of T = $40. The equilibrium price of hotel rooms rises from $80 to $100 a night, and the equilibrium quantity of rooms rented falls from 10 000 to 5000. Although hotel owners pay the tax, they actually bear only half the burden: the price they receive net of tax falls only $20, from $80 to $60. Guests who rent rooms bear the other half of the burden, because the price they pay rises by $20, from $80 to $100.

Let’s check this again. How do we know that 5000 rooms will be supplied at a price of $100? Because the price net of tax (PP = PCT) is $60, and according to the original supply curve, 5000 rooms will be supplied at a price of $60, as shown by point B in Figure 7-2.

Does this look familiar? It should. In Chapter 5 we described the effects of a quota on sales: a quota drives a wedge between the price paid by consumers and the price received by producers. An excise tax does the same thing. As a result of this wedge, consumers pay more (PC) and producers receive less (PP), with the gap being the tax wedge (T), so that PC = PP + T.

In our example, consumers—people who rent hotel rooms—end up paying $100 a night, $20 more than the pre-tax price of $80. At the same time, producers—the hotel owners—receive a price net of tax of $60 per room, $20 less than the pre-tax price. In addition, the tax creates missed opportunities: 5000 potential consumers who would have rented hotel rooms—those willing to pay $80 but not $100 per night—are discouraged from doing so. Correspondingly, 5000 rooms that would have been made available by hotel owners when they receive $80 are not offered when they receive only $60. Like a quota, this tax leads to inefficiency by distorting incentives and creating missed opportunities for mutually beneficial transactions.

It’s important to recognize that as we’ve described it, Potterville’s hotel tax is a tax on the hotel owners, not their guests—it’s a tax on the producers, not the consumers. Yet the price received by producers, net of tax (PP), is down by only $20, half the amount of the tax, and the price paid by consumers (PC) is up by $20. In effect, half the tax is actually being paid by consumers—the burden of the tax is shared between the suppliers and demanders.

What would happen if the city levied a tax on consumers instead of producers? That is, suppose that instead of requiring hotel owners to pay $40 a night for each room they rent, the city required hotel guests to pay $40 for each night they stayed in a hotel. The answer is shown in Figure 7-3. If a hotel guest must pay a tax of $40 per night, then the pre-tax price for a room paid by that guest must be reduced by $40 in order for the quantity of hotel rooms demanded post-tax to be the same as that demanded pre-tax. So the demand curve shifts downward by the amount of the tax from D1 to D2 = D1T.

Figure7-3An Excise Tax Imposed on Hotel Guests A $40 per room tax imposed on hotel guests shifts the demand curve from D1 to D2, a downward shift of $40. The equilibrium price of hotel rooms falls from $80 to $60 a night, and the quantity of rooms rented falls from 10 000 to 5000. Although in this case the tax is officially paid by (levied on, or collected from) consumers, while in Figure 7-2 the tax was paid by (collected from) producers, the outcome is the same: after taxes, hotel owners receive $60 per room but guests pay $100. This illustrates a general principle: The incidence of an excise tax doesn’t depend on whether the government levies the tax on consumers or producers.

At every quantity demanded, the demand price—the price that consumers must be offered to demand a given quantity—has fallen by $40. This shifts the equilibrium from E to B, where the market price of hotel rooms is $60 and 5000 hotel rooms are bought and sold. In effect, hotel guests pay $100 when you include the tax. So from the point of view of guests, it is as if they were on their original demand curve at point A.

If you compare Figures 7-2 and 7-3, you will immediately notice that they show the same price effect. In each case, consumers pay an effective price of $100 (PC), producers receive an effective price of $60 (PP), and 5000 hotel rooms are bought and sold. In fact, it doesn’t matter who the government officially asks to pay the tax—whether it’s levied on suppliers or consumers—the equilibrium outcome is the same.

The incidence of a tax is a measure of who really pays it.

This insight illustrates a general principle of the economics of taxation: the incidence of a tax—who really bears the burden of the tax—is typically not a question you can answer by asking who writes the cheque to the government. In this particular case, a $40 tax on hotel rooms is reflected in a $20 increase in the price paid by consumers and a $20 decrease in the price received by producers. Here, regardless of whether the tax is levied on consumers or producers, the incidence of the tax is evenly split between them.1

Price Elasticities and Tax Incidence

We’ve just learned that the economic incidence of an excise tax doesn’t depend on whom the government rules require to officially pay it. In the example shown in Figures 7-1 through 7-3, a tax on hotel rooms falls equally on consumers and producers, no matter who the tax is levied on. But it’s important to note that this 50–50 split between consumers and producers is a result of our assumptions in this example. In the real world, the incidence of an excise tax usually falls unevenly between consumers and producers, as one group bears more of the burden than the other.

What determines how the burden of an excise tax is allocated between consumers and producers? The answer depends on the shapes of the supply and the demand curves. More specifically, the incidence of an excise tax depends on the price elasticity of supply and the price elasticity of demand. We can see this by looking first at a case in which consumers pay most of an excise tax, then at a case in which producers pay most of the tax.

When an Excise Tax Is Paid Mainly by Consumers Figure 7-4 shows an excise tax that falls mainly on consumers: an excise tax on gasoline, which we set at $0.25 per litre. (There really is a federal excise tax on gasoline, though it is actually only $0.10 per litre in Canada. In addition, provinces, territories, and even several cities impose excise taxes between $0.09 and $0.24 per litre. Finally, the GST/HST and, if applicable, provincial sales taxes also apply to gasoline sales.) According to Figure 7-4, in the absence of the tax, gasoline would sell for $1.05 per litre.

Figure7-4An Excise Tax Paid Mainly by Consumers The relatively steep demand curve here reflects a low price elasticity of demand for gasoline. The relatively flat supply curve reflects a high price elasticity of supply. The pre-tax price of a litre of gasoline is $1.05, and a tax of $0.25 per litre is imposed. The price paid by consumers rises by $0.20 to $1.25, reflecting the fact that most of the burden of the tax falls on consumers. Only a small portion of the tax is borne by producers: the price they receive falls by only $0.05 to $1.00.

Two key assumptions are reflected in the shapes of the supply and demand curves in Figure 7-4. First, the price elasticity of demand for gasoline is assumed to be very low, so the demand curve is relatively steep. Recall that a low price elasticity of demand means that the quantity demanded changes little in response to a change in price—a feature of a steep demand curve. Second, the price elasticity of supply of gasoline is assumed to be very high, so the supply curve is relatively flat. A high price elasticity of supply means that the quantity supplied changes a lot in response to a change in price—a feature of a relatively flat supply curve.

We have just learned that an excise tax drives a wedge, equal to the size of the tax, between the price paid by consumers and the price received by producers. This wedge drives the price paid by consumers up and the price received by producers down. But as we can see from Figure 7-4, in this case those two effects are very unequal in size. The price received by producers falls only slightly, from $1.05 to $1.00, but the price paid by consumers rises by a lot, from $1.05 to $1.25. In this case consumers bear the greater share of the tax burden.

This example illustrates another general principle of taxation: When the price elasticity of demand is low and the price elasticity of supply is high, the burden of an excise tax falls mainly on consumers. Why? A low price elasticity of demand means that consumers have few substitutes and so little alternative to buying higher-priced gasoline. In contrast, a high price elasticity of supply results from the fact that producers have many production substitutes for their gasoline (that is, other uses for the crude oil from which gasoline is refined). This gives producers much greater flexibility in refusing to accept lower prices for their gasoline. And, not surprisingly, the party with the least flexibility—in this case, consumers—gets stuck paying most of the tax. This is a good description of how the burden of the main excise taxes actually collected in Canada today, such as those on cigarettes and alcoholic beverages, is allocated between consumers and producers.

When an Excise Tax Is Paid Mainly by Producers Figure 7-5 shows an example of an excise tax paid mainly by producers, a $5.00 per day tax on downtown parking in a small city. In the absence of the tax, the market equilibrium price of parking is $6.00 per day.

Figure7-5An Excise Tax Paid Mainly by Producers The relatively flat demand curve here reflects a high price elasticity of demand for downtown parking, and the relatively steep supply curve results from a low price elasticity of supply. The pre-tax price of a daily parking space is $6.00 and a tax of $5.00 is imposed. The price received by producers falls a lot, to $1.50, reflecting the fact that they bear most of the tax burden. The price paid by consumers rises a small amount, $0.50, to $6.50, so they bear very little of the burden.

We’ve assumed in this case that the price elasticity of supply is very low because the lots used for parking have very few alternative uses. This makes the supply curve for parking spaces relatively steep. The price elasticity of demand, however, is assumed to be high: consumers can easily switch from the downtown spaces to other parking spaces a few minutes’ walk from downtown, spaces that are not subject to the tax. This makes the demand curve relatively flat.

The tax drives a wedge between the price paid by consumers and the price received by producers. In this example, however, the tax causes the price paid by consumers to rise only slightly, from $6.00 to $6.50, but the price received by producers falls a lot, from $6.00 to $1.50. In the end, consumers bear only $0.50 of the $5.00 tax burden, with producers bearing the remaining $4.50.

Again, this example illustrates a general principle: When the price elasticity of demand is high and the price elasticity of supply is low, the burden of an excise tax falls mainly on producers. A real-world example is a tax on purchases of existing houses. Just before the recession hit Canada in 2008, the cash-strapped city of Toronto implemented a municipal land transfer tax to raise revenue. A land transfer tax is collected as a percentage of the price at which a residential or commercial property sells. To politicians, the idea was simple: homes sales were strong and in the preceding years prices had steadily risen. The tax rate was designed to rise somewhat as the price increased, so to some degree the higher the price paid the more tax paid in both relative and absolute terms. So besides helping the city meet its budgetary needs, the tax was intended to be paid mostly by well-off outsiders moving into desirable locations and purchasing homes from the less well-off original occupants. But this ignores the fact that the price elasticity of demand for houses in Toronto is often high, because potential buyers can choose to move to other towns. Furthermore, the price elasticity of supply is often low because most sellers must sell their houses due to job transfers or to provide funds for their retirement. So taxes on home purchases are actually paid mainly by the less well-off sellers—not, as Toronto officials may have imagined, by wealthy buyers.2

Putting It All Together We’ve just seen that when the price elasticity of supply is high and the price elasticity of demand is low, an excise tax falls mainly on consumers. And when the price elasticity of supply is low and the price elasticity of demand is high, an excise tax falls mainly on producers. This leads us to the general rule: When the price elasticity of demand is higher than the price elasticity of supply, an excise tax falls mainly on producers. When the price elasticity of supply is higher than the price elasticity of demand, an excise tax falls mainly on consumers. So it is elasticity—not the tax legislation—that determines the incidence of an excise tax.

WHO PAYS CANADA’S PAYROLL TAXES?

Contrary to widely held beliefs, for many Canadians it’s payroll taxes, not the income tax, that takes the biggest bite from their paycheques.

Anyone who works for an employer receives a paycheque that itemizes not only the wages paid but also the money deducted from the paycheque for various taxes. For most people, one of the big deductions is for Canada’s various payroll taxes. Nationally these payroll taxes fund the Canada Pension Plan (CPP), a national pension plan for Canada’s workers (workers in Quebec contribute to the Quebec Pension Plan (QPP)), and Employment Insurance (EI), an insurance program that provides assistance to many of Canada’s workers during spells of unemployment. At the provincial level, payroll taxes exist to fund worker compensation systems for injured workers and, in some cases, to help fund provincial health and education spending.

In 2013, most Canadian workers paid 6.83% of about the first $50 000 of their earnings in CPP (4.95%) and EI (1.88%) contributions. But this isn’t even the half of it: each employer is required to pay an amount equal to the CPP contributions and 1.4 times the EI contributions of its employees. And when it comes to the various other provincial payroll taxes, which range from 1.12% to as much as 6.34%, the employer is expected to pay the entire amount.

How should we think about Canada’s payroll taxes? Are they really shared by workers and employers? We can use our previous analysis to answer that question because payroll taxes are like an excise tax—a tax on the sale and purchase of labour. A portion of it is a tax levied on the sellers—that is, workers. The rest is a tax levied on the buyers—that is, employers.

But we already know that the incidence of a tax does not really depend on who actually makes out the cheque. Almost all economists agree that payroll taxes are more costly for workers than for their employers. The reason for this conclusion lies in a comparison of the price elasticities of the supply of labour by households and the demand for labour by firms. Evidence indicates that the price elasticity of demand for labour is quite high, at least 3. That is, an increase in average wages of 1% would lead to at least a 3% decline in the number of hours of work demanded by employers. Labour economists believe, however, that the price elasticity of supply of labour is very low. The reason is that although a fall in the wage rate reduces the incentive to work more hours, it also makes people poorer and less able to afford leisure time. The strength of this second effect is shown in the data: the number of hours people are willing to work falls very little—if at all—when the wage per hour goes down.

Our general rule of tax incidence says that when the price elasticity of demand is much higher than the price elasticity of supply, the burden of an excise tax falls mainly on the suppliers. So the burden of Canada’s payroll taxes falls mainly on the suppliers of labour, that is, workers—even though on paper most of these taxes are paid by employers. Payroll taxes are largely borne by workers in the form of lower wages, rather than by employers in the form of lower profits.

This conclusion tells us something important about the Canadian tax system: payroll taxes, rather than the much-maligned income tax, are the main tax burden on families in the lower half of the income distribution. For most workers, payroll taxes amount to more than 15.5% of all wages and salaries up to about $50 000 per year (note that 6.83% + 4.95% + 1.4 × 1.88% + 1.12% = 15.532%). Thus, the great majority of workers in Canada pay at least 15.5% of their wages in payroll taxes. Meanwhile, only middle- and high-income Canadian families pay more than 15% of their income in income tax. In fact, according to the Fraser Institute, the average Canadian household earned an income of $74 113 in 2012 and paid $9195 in income taxes and $6769 in payroll taxes, which represented 29.1% and 21.4% of the total taxes paid by such a family. So for the average family, payroll taxes represent their second largest tax burden.

Quick Review

  • An excise tax drives a wedge between the price paid by consumers and that received by producers, leading to a fall in the quantity transacted. It creates inefficiency by distorting incentives and creating missed opportunities.

  • The incidence of an excise tax doesn’t depend on whom the tax is officially levied on. Rather, it depends on the price elasticities of demand and of supply.

  • The higher the price elasticity of supply and the lower the price elasticity of demand, the heavier the burden of an excise tax on consumers. The lower the price elasticity of supply and the higher the price elasticity of demand, the heavier the burden on producers.

Check Your Understanding 7-1

CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING 7-1

Question 7.1

Consider the market for butter, shown in the accompanying figure. The government imposes an excise tax of $0.30 per kilogram of butter. What is the price paid by consumers post-tax? What is the price received by producers post-tax? What is the quantity of butter transacted? How is the incidence of the tax allocated between consumers and producers? Show this on the figure.

The following figure shows that, after introduction of the excise tax, the price paid by consumers rises to $1.20; the price received by producers falls to $0.90. Consumers bear $0.20 of the $0.30 tax per kilogram of butter; producers bear $0.10 of the $0.30 tax per kilogram of butter. The tax drives a wedge of $0.30 between the price paid by consumers and the price received by producers. As a result, the quantity of butter bought and sold is now 9 million kilograms.

Question 7.2

The demand for economics textbooks is very inelastic, but the supply is somewhat elastic. What does this imply about the incidence of an excise tax? Illustrate with a diagram.

The fact that demand is very inelastic means that consumers will reduce their demand for textbooks very little in response to an increase in the price caused by the tax. The fact that supply is somewhat elastic means that suppliers will respond to the fall in the price by reducing supply. As a result, the incidence of the tax will fall heavily on consumers of economics textbooks and very little on publishers, as shown in the accompanying figure.

Question 7.3

True or false? When a substitute for a good is readily available to consumers, but it is difficult for producers to adjust the quantity of the good produced, then the burden of a tax on the good falls more heavily on producers.

True. When a substitute is readily available, demand is elastic. This implies that producers cannot easily pass on the cost of the tax to consumers because consumers will respond to an increased price by switching to the substitute. Furthermore, when producers have difficulty adjusting the amount of the good produced, supply is inelastic. That is, producers cannot easily reduce output in response to a lower price net of tax. So the tax burden will fall more heavily on producers than consumers.

Question 7.4

The supply of bottled spring water is very inelastic, but the demand for it is somewhat elastic. What does this imply about the incidence of a tax? Illustrate with a diagram.

The fact that supply is very inelastic means that producers will reduce their supply of bottled water very little in response to the fall in price caused by the tax. Demand, on the other hand, will fall in response to an increase in price because demand is somewhat elastic. As a result, the incidence of the tax will fall heavily on producers of bottled spring water and very little on consumers, as shown in the accompanying figure.

Question 7.5

True or false? Other things equal, consumers would prefer to face a less elastic supply curve for a good or service when an excise tax is imposed.

True. The lower the elasticity of supply, the more the burden of a tax will fall on producers rather than consumers, other things equal.