Oligopoly

oligopoly A market with just a few firms dominating the industry, where (1) each firm recognizes that it must consider its competitors’ reactions when making its own decisions (mutual interdependence), and (2) there are significant barriers to entry into the market.

Oligopoly markets are those in which a large market share is controlled by just a few firms. What constitutes a few firms controlling a large market share is not rigidly defined. Further, these firms can sell either a homogeneous product (e.g., gasoline, sugar) or a differentiated product (e.g., automobiles, pharmaceuticals).

Industries can be composed of a dominant firm with a few smaller firms making up the rest of the industry (e.g., computer operating systems), or the industry can be composed of a few similarly sized firms (e.g., automobiles, tobacco). The point of this discussion is that oligopoly models are numerous and varied, and we will explore only a few. Oligopoly models do, however, have several common characteristics.

Defining Oligopoly

All oligopoly models share several common assumptions:

Because there are only a few firms, each firm possesses substantial market power. However, because the products sold by oligopolists are similar to each other, the actions of one will affect the ability of the others to sell or price their output successfully. If one firm changes the specifications of its product or increases its advertising budget, this will have an impact on its rivals, and they can be expected to respond in kind. Thus, one firm cannot forecast its change in sales for a new promotion without first making some assumption about the reaction of its rivals.

In an industry composed of just a few firms, entry scale is often huge. Plus, with just a few firms, typically brand preferences are quite strong on the part of consumers, and a new firm may need a substantial marketing program just to get a foot in the door. For example, the investment in a plant for a new automaker is huge, and the marketing effort also must be large to get people to even consider a new auto brand.

Cartels: Joint Profit Maximization and the Instability of Oligopolies

Cartels are theft —usually by well-dressed thieves.

cartel An agreement between firms (or countries) in an industry to formally collude on price and output, then agree on the distribution of production.

GRAEME SAMUEL, HEAD OF AUSTRALIA’S ANTITRUST OFFICE

The first oligopoly model we examine is collusive joint profit maximization, or a cartel model. Here we assume that a few firms collude (combine secretly) to operate like a monopoly, using maximum market power to set the monopoly price and output and share the monopoly profits. Cartels are illegal in the United States and in the European Union, although international laws do not ban them.

The most famous cartel operating today is OPEC, the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries. OPEC countries meet to establish an output level that each individual member can produce, thus pushing up prices and carving up shares of the profits. OPEC, formed principally of Middle Eastern countries in the early 1960s, really didn’t become effective until 1973 when member countries took greater control of their domestic oil industries. Today, however, competition from non-OPEC countries in Africa, Northern Europe, and Canada is slowly reducing the power of OPEC.

254

Figure 4 illustrates a hypothetical cartel consisting of five firms. By forming a cartel, these five firms agree to fix their overall output equal to the profit maximizing output of a monopolist, which is 100. At this restricted output, each cartel member produces its fixed quota of output (20 units per firm, assuming the cartel divides total output equally), and shares the resulting profit. Under this scenario, the cartel exhibits maximum market power equal to a single-firm monopolist.

Cartels and the Incentive to Cheat A cartel consisting of five firms collectively agrees to restrict total output to the monopoly output of 100 units and charges $10 per unit. If one firm chooses to cheat by increasing its output by an additional 20 units, total output increases to 120 units and price falls to $8. This results in a loss of revenue of $200, which is shared equally among the five cartel members ($40 loss per member, equal to one share of the yellow area). However, the cheating member gains $160 from the additional 20 units sold at $8 each (green area). The marginal revenue for the cheating member is therefore $160 − $40 = $120.

However, cartels are inherently unstable because of the incentive to cheat by individual members. Although the cartel as a whole is maximizing profits, each individual member can potentially earn more profits by producing more than its output quota. As illustrated in Figure 4, if one firm exceeds its quota by doubling output from 20 to 40, the overall output of the cartel increases from 100 to 120 units. By expanding production, the market price falls from $10 to $8, causing revenues to fall by $200 ($2 × 100 units), shown as the yellow area. This reduction in revenues is shared by all five firms, with each firm losing $40 (or one share of the yellow area). Despite this loss, the cheating firm benefits because the extra 20 units it produces earns the firm $160 in additional revenue ($8 × 20 units), shown as the green area. The marginal revenue from cheating is therefore $160 − $40 = $120. As long as the marginal cost of producing the extra 20 units is less than $120, the firm benefits from cheating on the cartel agreement.

However, when one firm cheats, this often leads to other firms cheating. As more and more cartel members cheat, the price continues to fall toward the competitive price, greatly hurting the noncheating members. Over time, the cartel falls apart when all members increase their output, resulting in a competitive outcome. Therefore, market power in a cartel can range from the monopoly case (if all members adhere to their quotas) to the competitive case when cartels completely break down.

One reason that cartels are inherently unstable is because increasing output by one member can be undetected. However, once quotas are breached, the effects on all other members expand, increasing the likelihood of more cheating, especially if the marginal cost of production is low. For oil-producing countries, additional production is particularly profitable because a $100 barrel of oil may only cost $10 to $20 to produce. Each firm in the cartel faces these incentives, and if many attempt to sell additional output, the cartel agreement will break down. This analysis has led some economists to lose interest in cartels, because cartels are likely to fail in the long run.

Although cartels are inherently unstable, certain factors can enhance the likelihood of the cartel’s survival. First, cartel stability is enhanced with fewer members with similar goals. With fewer members, any action that breaches the cartel agreement is more easily noticed and punishable. Second, stability is improved if the cartel is maintained with legal provisions (such as government protection). Third, stability is improved if firms are unable to differentiate their products (such as providing enhanced service or some other product as an inducement to purchase). Fourth, stability is improved when each firm’s cost structure is similar, thereby not giving any firm a cost advantage over another. Finally, a cartel is more stable when there are significant barriers to entry preventing new firms from competing against existing cartel members.

255

These factors do not bode well for the future of the twelve member countries of OPEC. Although OPEC members produce a uniform product (crude oil) and have similar cost structures, enforcement of the quotas has at times been shaky with politically unstable countries. Further, OPEC’s total share of world oil production has been surpassed by non-OPEC countries, led by Russia, the United States, Mexico, Canada, China, and Brazil. Maintaining an effective oil cartel will become more difficult as more countries enter the industry and as new alternative fuels are developed.

The Kinked Demand Curve Model and the Stability of Oligopolies

Oligopoly industries share a characteristic that prices tend to be stable for extended periods of time. For example, prices for wireless data plans are often $39.99 per month, and prices of unlimited texting plans are usually $19.99 per month. Why do these prices tend to stay the same when the underlying costs of providing the services change?

A study by Sweezy, Hall, and Hitch in the 1930s recognized that prices tended to be stable for extended periods in oligopolistic industries. It was in an effort to model this price stability that they settled on the idea of a kinked demand curve.

Demand curve d in Figure 5 represents the demand for one firm when all other firms in the industry do not follow its price changes. Demand curve D represents demand when all other firms raise or lower prices in concert. Demand curve d is relatively more elastic than demand curve D because when the firm raises prices and others do not follow, quantity demanded declines rapidly as customers substitute to the now lower priced products from competitors. Similarly, when one firm’s prices fall and the others ignore this change, demand for the lower priced products grows rapidly. Hence, demand curve d is relatively elastic.

The Kinked Demand Curve Model of Oligopoly The kinked demand curve model of oligopoly shows why oligopoly prices appear stable. The model assumes that if the firm raised its price, competitors will not react and raise their prices, but if the firm lowers its price, other firms will lower theirs in response. These reactions create a “kink” in the firm’s demand curve at point e, and a discontinuity in the MR curve equal to the distance between points a and b. This discontinuity permits marginal costs to vary from MC0 to MC1 before the firm will change its price.

Demand curve D, on the other hand, is more like the industry demand. When all firms raise and lower their prices together, demand will be less elastic than demand curve d.

kinked demand curve An oligopoly model that assumes that if a firm raises its price, competitors will not raise theirs; but if the firm lowers its price, all of its competitors will lower their price to match the reduction. This leads to a kink in the demand curve and relatively stable market prices.

256

The kinked demand curve model assumes the following:

As a result, the relevant demand curve facing the firm is the darkened portion of demand curves d and D that is kinked at point e. The relevant portion of the marginal revenue curve is the darkened dashed curve MR with the discontinuity between points a and b. Notice, we are just using the relevant portions of MRd and MRD. As shown, marginal cost crosses through the discontinuity, resulting in an equilibrium price and output of P0 and Q0.

It is, of course, the discontinuity in the MR curve that gives this model its price stability. The marginal cost curve can vary anywhere between points a and b before the firm will have any incentive to change prices to maximize profits.

The analysis of unstable and stable oligopoly models underscores the importance of the mutual interdependence of firms. How one firm reacts to a competitor’s market strategy determines the nature of competition in the industry. These ideas led to game theory, which we consider in the next section.

OLIGOPOLY

  • Oligopolies are markets (a) with only a few firms, (b) where each firm takes into account the reaction of rivals to its policies or firms recognize their mutual interdependence, and (c) where there are significant barriers to entry.
  • The market power for an oligopoly can be substantial, although the ability of a firm to utilize its market power fully depends on its interdependence with competing firms.
  • Cartels result when several firms collude to set market price and output. Cartels typically use their market power to act like monopolists and share the economic profits that result.
  • Cartels are inherently unstable because individual firms can earn higher profits by selling more than their allotted quota. As more firms in the cartel cheat, prices fall, defeating the agreement.
  • The observation that prices are stable in oligopoly industries (other than in cartels) gave rise to the kinked demand curve model. The model assumes that competitors will follow price reductions but not price increases. This leads to a discontinuity in MR, permitting cost to vary substantially before prices are changed.

QUESTION: The major drug cartels operating along the U.S.–Mexico border have become increasingly violent in recent years as cartels try to protect their trafficking routes to the U.S. market from competitors. But in addition to conflicts with external competition, cartel members have been murdered for exceeding their distribution quotas. Given the nature of how cartels function, explain why cartel leaders have become increasingly violent as a result of the above events.



A cartel functions best when its members adhere to the established quotas (which keep prices for drugs high) and also when no external competition exists (allowing the cartel to operate as if it were a monopoly). Competition from noncartel drug traffickers as well as cartel members exceeding their production quotas poses a threat to the cartel’s existence, and hence cartels will often use violence to prevent those activities from occurring. When the drug trade is dominated by several large and powerful organizations, the actions of one organization have a significant effect on the others, an example of the mutual interdependence of firms in an oligopoly.