Total Revenue and Other Measures of Elasticity

Elasticity is important to firms because elasticity measures the responsiveness of quantity sold to changes in price, which provides valuable information to firms in deciding whether to increase or decrease prices. Owners of a restaurant that is completely full each evening might ponder raising its prices, but only if it can retain most of its customers. Another restaurant, which has few customers, might wish to lower its prices to generate more business, but only if it generates enough business to offset the lower prices it charges.

Elasticity is also important because it allows firms to determine how a change in the price of one product might affect the demand for other items, or how changes in economic conditions might affect the market for their goods. If a supermarket discounts the price of sirloin steaks, how would this affect the demand for other cuts of beef, or other meats? Would it increase sales of steak sauce and potatoes? These are questions we address in this section using other measures of elasticity.

110

Elasticity and Total Revenue

total revenue Price × quantity demanded (sold). If demand is elastic and price rises, quantity demanded falls off significantly and total revenue declines, and vice versa. If demand is inelastic and price rises, quantity demanded does not decline much and total revenue rises, and vice versa.

The elasticity of demand, which we learned about in the previous section, has an important effect on the total revenues of the firm. Total revenue (TR) is equal to the number of units sold (Q) times the price of each unit (P), or

TR = Q × P

The sensitivity of output sold to price changes greatly influences how much total revenue changes when price changes.

Inelastic Demand When consumers are so loyal to a product or so few substitutes exist that consumers continue to buy the product even when its price goes up, the product is inelastically demanded. Panel A of Figure 3 shows the impact such a price increase has on total revenue when the demand for a product is inelastic. Price rises from $2.00 to $4.00, and sales decline from 600 to 500 units. In this case, total revenue rises. We know this because the revenue gained from the price hike [($4.00 − $2.00) × 500 = $1,000] is greater than the revenue lost [($2.00 × (600 − 500) = $200]. We can see this by comparing the size of the area labeled “Revenue Gained” with the area labeled “Revenue Lost” in the figure. What has happened here? The price hike has driven off only a few customers, but the firm’s many remaining customers are paying a much higher price, thus driving up the firm’s total revenue.

Total Revenue and Elasticity of Demand Given inelastic demand in panel A, when price rises from $2 to $4, revenue rises because the revenue gained from the price hike ($1,000) is greater than the revenue lost from fewer sales ($200). The price hike may have driven off a few customers, but the firm’s many remaining customers are paying a much higher price, thus increasing the firm’s revenue. When products have elastic demands as shown in panel B, usually because many substitutes are available, firms feel a greater impact from changes in price. A small rise in price causes sales to fall off dramatically.

This may suggest that firms would always want the demand for their products to be inelastic. Unfortunately for them, inelastic demand has a flip side. Specifically, if supply increases (due to a technical advance, say), sales will rise only moderately, even as prices fall dramatically. This leads to a drop in total revenue: Consumers indeed buy more of the product at its new lower price, but not enough to offset the lower price per unit received by firms.

111

Elastic Demand Elastic demand is the opposite of inelastic demand. Firms with elastically demanded products will see their sales change dramatically in response to small price changes. Panel B of Figure 3 shows what happens to total revenue when a firm increases the price of a product with elastic demand. Although price does not increase much, sales fall significantly. Revenue lost greatly exceeds the revenue gained from the price increase, thus total revenue falls.

The opposite occurs when prices fall and demand is elastic. The high elasticity of demand faced by restaurants helps explain why so many of them offer “Happy Hour” specials and other discounts. As prices fall, sales have the potential to expand rapidly, thus increasing revenue.

Unitary Elasticity We have looked at the impact of changing prices on revenue when demand is elastic and inelastic. When the elasticity of demand is unitary (Ed = 1), a 10% increase in price results in a 10% reduction in quantity demanded. As a result, total revenue is unaffected.

Table 2 summarizes the effects price changes have on total revenue for different price elasticities of demand.

Elasticity and Total Revenue Along a Straight-Line (Linear) Demand Curve Elasticity varies along a straight-line demand curve. Figure 4 shows a linear demand curve in panel A and graphs the corresponding total revenue points in panel B. In panel A, the elastic part of the curve is that portion above point e. Notice that when price falls from $11 to $10, the revenue gained ($100) is much larger than the revenue lost ($10), and thus total revenue rises. This is shown in panel B, where total revenue rises when output grows from 10 to 20 units.

Price Elasticity and Total Revenue Along a Straight Line (Linear) Demand Curve Price elasticity varies along a straight line demand curve. In panel A, the elastic part of the curve lies above point e. Thus, when price falls from $11 to $10, revenue rises, as shown in panel B. As we move down the demand curve, elasticity equals 1 (at point e) where elasticity is unitary. Revenue is maximized at this point. As price continues to fall below $6, demand moves into an inelastic range. When price falls from $3 to $2, revenue declines, as shown in panel B.

As we move down the demand curve, elasticity will eventually equal 1 (at point e) where elasticity is unitary. Price was falling up to this point, while total revenue kept rising until the last price reduction just before $6, where revenue did not change. Revenue is at its maximum at point e or a price of $6 in both panels.

As price continues to fall below $6, the demand curve moves into an inelastic range because the percentage change in quantity demanded is less than the percentage change in price. Therefore, when price falls from $3 to $2, revenue declines. The revenue gained ($20) is less than the revenue lost ($90). This decline in revenue is shown in panel B, as total revenue falls as output rises from 90 to 100 units sold.

To summarize, elasticity changes along a negatively sloped linear demand curve because the percentage change in price and quantity varies along the curve. When the price of a product is low, a 1-unit change in price is a large percentage change while the percentage change in quantity demanded is small. When the price is high, a 1-unit change in price is a small percentage change but the percentage change in quantity is large.

112

Other Elasticities of Demand

Besides the price elasticity of demand, two other elasticities of demand are important. The first, cross elasticity of demand, measures how changes in the price of one good affect the demand for other related goods. If Toyota is planning a price reduction, what impact will this have on the sale of Fords? Ford will want to estimate this to decide whether to ignore Toyota or lower its own automobile prices.

Another type of elasticity measures how responsive quantity demanded is to changes in income. This is called income elasticity of demand. Incomes vary as the economy expands and contracts. To plan their future employment and production, many industries want to know how the demand for their products will be affected when the economy changes. How much will airline travel be affected if the economy moves into a recession? What will happen to sales of lattes at Starbucks? Each business faces a different situation.

Let’s consider these two elasticities of demand more closely, beginning with cross elasticity of demand.

cross elasticity of demand Measures how responsive the quantity demanded of one good is to changes in the price of another good. Substitute goods have positive cross elasticities: An increase in the price of one good leads consumers to substitute (buy more of) the other good whose price has not changed. Complementary goods have negative cross elasticities: An increase in the price of a complement leads to a reduction in sales of the other good whose price has not changed.

Cross Elasticity of Demand Cross elasticity of demand (Eab) measures how responsive the quantity demanded of one good (product a) is to changes in the price of another (product b):

substitutes Goods consumers substitute for one another depending on their relative prices, such as coffee and tea. Substitutes have a positive cross elasticity of demand.

113

complements Goods that are typically consumed together, such as coffee and sugar. Complements have a negative cross elasticity of demand.

Using cross elasticity of demand, we can classify goods in two ways. Products a and b are substitutes if their cross elasticity of demand is positive (Eab > 0). Common sense tells us that chicken and turkey are substitutes. Therefore, if the price of turkey rises, people will substitute away from turkey and toward chicken, thus the quantity demanded for chicken will grow. This illustrates a positive cross elasticity. Similar relationships exist between Toyota and Honda cars, wireless services provided by AT&T and Verizon, and the price of gas and public transportation.

Second, products a and b are >complements> if their cross elasticity of demand is negative (Eab < 0). This is an instance in which a minus sign conveys important information. Complementary products are those goods and services that are consumed together, such as lift tickets and snowboard rentals. When the price of lift tickets rises, the result is that the quantity demanded for snowboard rentals falls as fewer people head to the mountains. Other complementary goods include coffee and cream, hamburgers and french fries, and hot dogs and hot dog buns. Finally, two goods are not related if a cross elasticity of demand is zero, or near zero.

income elasticity of demand Measures how responsive quantity demanded is to changes in consumer income.

Income Elasticity of Demand The income elasticity of demand (EY) measures how responsive quantity demanded is to changes in consumer income. We define the income elasticity of demand as

normal goods Goods that have positive income elasticities of less than 1. When consumer income grows, quantity demanded rises for normal goods, but less than the rise in income.

luxury goods Goods that have income elasticities greater than 1. When consumer income grows, quantity demanded of luxury goods rises more than the rise in income.

Depending on the value of the income elasticity of demand, we can classify goods in three ways. First, a normal good is one whose income elasticity is positive, but less than 1 (0 < EY < 1). As income rises, quantity demanded rises as well, but not as fast as the rise in income. Most products are normal goods. If your income doubles, you will probably buy more sporting equipment and restaurant meals, but not twice as many.

inferior goods Goods that have income elasticities that are negative. When consumer income grows, quantity demanded falls for inferior goods.

A second category, income superior goods or luxury goods, includes products with an income elasticity greater than 1 (EY > 1). As income rises, quantity demanded grows faster than income. Goods and services such as Mercedes automobiles, caviar, fine wine, and visits to European spas are luxury or income superior goods.

Finally, inferior goods are those goods for which income elasticity is negative (EY < 0). When income rises, the quantity demanded for these goods falls. Inferior goods include potatoes, beans, cheap motels, and nosebleed section concert tickets. Get yourself a nice raise, and you will probably buy concert tickets that let you see the band up close and personal.

Keep in mind that inferior goods are not necessarily poor in quality; they simply describe goods that one buys fewer of as income increases, and vice versa. Therefore, inferior goods can vary from person to person. Nosebleed seats might be an inferior good for an avid concertgoer, but can be a normal good to a person who rarely goes to concerts.

After college, incomes rise, which means fewer packed lunches on the lawn and more fancy lunches at the local bistro.
Ocean/Corbis

Understanding how product sales are affected by changing incomes and economic conditions can help firms to diversify their product lines so that sales and employment can be stabilized to some extent over time. For example, firms that produce all three types of goods can try to switch production toward the good that current economic conditions favor: In boom times, production is shifted more toward the making of luxury goods. Chevrolet will produce more Corvettes in boom times, and more Chevy Sparks during economic slowdowns.

This is a good place to stop and reflect on what we have discovered so far. We have seen that elasticity measures the responsiveness of one variable to changes in another. Elasticity measures changes in percentage terms so that products of different magnitudes—a bottle of soda and an airplane—can be compared. Products that have a price elasticity of demand greater than 1 are elastic; products with price elasticity of demand less than 1 are inelastic; and products with a price elasticity of demand equal to 1 are unitary elastic. We saw how total revenue increases when price rises for an inelastic good but decreases when price rises for an elastic good. Finally, we saw that elasticity can be used to measure the effects of related goods using cross elasticity of demand, as well as changes in income using income elasticity of demand.

114

Using Loss Leaders to Generate Higher Total Revenue


At the start of each school year, office supply stores will often advertise items for as low as one cent. These items typically are essential school supplies such as paper, pencils, and folders that parents need to buy for their children. Because school supplies are necessities and generally low-priced, they are relatively inelastic goods. Why, then, would stores choose to reduce their prices, knowing that such actions would lead to a fall in total revenue?

The answer lies not in how prices for school supplies affect total revenue, but instead the effect that those remarkably low prices, known as loss leaders, has on the cross elasticity of demand for more pricier items, such as laptops, color printers, and office furniture, sold at the store. In other words, the practically free school supplies are used as an incentive to attract parents into the store.

Barbara Helgason/Dreamstime.com

Wouldn’t some parents just buy the school supplies on sale and nothing else? Some actually do. However, most stores place limits on the quantity of the discounted items that can be purchased. Further, the inelastic nature of school supplies means that parents are not likely to hoard large quantities of school supplies because of the reduction in prices. More important, the potential gain from just one customer choosing to buy a high-priced computer or printer would offset the lost revenue from the loss leaders many times over. And because the start of the school year is when many high-priced school items are purchased, few parents end up buying just the advertised items.

Loss leaders are an effective advertising tool to increase total revenues from the sale of higher priced related goods. And loss leaders are not limited to office supply stores. Other examples of loss leaders include convenience stores advertising a free soda or coffee on large banners visible to potential customers at the gas pump, fast-food restaurants featuring a 99 cent sandwich special on their marquee, or a campus sporting goods store offering a free T-shirt just for stopping by. In each case, stores are betting on consumers making decisions beyond that of the loss leader, thus illustrating the importance of cross elasticity of demand in business decisions.

TOTAL REVENUE AND OTHER MEASURES OF ELASTICITY

  • When demand is inelastic and prices rise, total revenue rises. When demand is inelastic and prices fall, total revenue falls.
  • When demand is elastic and prices rise, total revenue falls. When demand is elastic and prices fall, total revenue rises.
  • Straight line demand curves have elastic (at higher prices) and inelastic (at lower prices) ranges.
  • Cross elasticity of demand measures how responsive the quantity demanded of one product is to price changes of another. Substitutes have positive cross elasticities while complements have negative cross elasticities.
  • Income elasticity of demand is a measure of how responsive quantity demanded is to changes in income. This determines whether a good is a luxury, normal, or inferior good.

QUESTION: Two clothing stores located in the same shopping center have a big sale: 20% off on everything in the store. After the sale, store 1 finds that its total revenue has increased, while store 2 finds that total revenue has decreased. What does this tell you about the price elasticity of demand for the clothes in stores 1 and 2?



Store 1 has an elastic demand for its clothes, while store 2 faces an inelastic demand. Look back at Table 2.

115