135

Consumer Choice and Demand

6

image
Understanding how consumers make choices to maximize their well-being given the resource constraints they face
altrendo images/Getty Images

136

Learning Objectives

6.1 Use a budget line to determine the constraints on consumer choices.

6.2 Determine how budget lines change when prices or income changes.

6.3 Describe the difference between total and marginal utility.

6.4 Explain the law of diminishing marginal utility.

6.5 Define the utility maximization rule and explain how it optimizes consumption given a budget.

6.6 Equate the marginal utility per dollar between two or more goods.

6.7 Explain why individuals sometimes make irrational decisions in predictable ways.

6.8 Describe five psychological factors that influence economic decision making.

Each day, virtually every person makes consumption choices, whether that means going to the mall to buy a new outfit, to a restaurant to dine with friends, or to the supermarket to stock up on groceries. The consumption choices that people make form what we have described as demand. But how do consumers make these choices? One of the important lessons from prior chapters is that individuals aim to maximize their well-being given a limited amount of resources.

In order to make consumption choices, individuals must first determine what choices of goods and services are affordable given their budget. Although we naturally think of income as the primary determinant of what can be afforded, prices also play a key role. Think of how a sale at a department store increases the amount of goods we can buy, or how higher energy prices restrict what we can spend on other goods. Once we know what we can afford, the next question is then how to allocate budgets to maximize our well-being.

The process by which individuals choose goods and services to maximize their overall happiness can be tricky to analyze. The main reason is that demand analysis rests on an important assumption: People are rational decision makers. Do people always act rationally? Of course not. You might spend more money eating out than you had wanted because your friends convinced you to go, which then caused you to give up buying a new shirt that would have given you more satisfaction. In these situations, individuals often come to realize that money is not always spent in the optimal manner; if it were, we would never regret the spontaneous purchases we make.

The fact that individuals sometimes make irrational decisions makes the analysis of consumer choice difficult to predict. However, a number of economists, called behavioralists, have been studying certain situations in which people make irrational decisions. What these economists have found is that although the decisions we make may sometimes appear irrational, they are irrational in predictable ways. For example, after paying $100 to enter a theme park only to find it crowded and unbearably hot, would you be reluctant to leave right away? Or, a person attempting to start a diet program may purchase a long-term plan given an optimistic anticipation of completing the program, only to give up after a few months. These examples illustrate how psychological factors influence our consumption choices in ways that lead to decisions economists would view as irrational.

Although this work on the irrational is important, it does not discredit the assumption that people choose rationally. If there were a preponderance of irrationality, society would come to a halt because we could not predict anything. What pedestrian would cross the street even if the light said “walk” if there was a modicum of fear that drivers would act irrationally and ignore a red light? People do miss or ignore red lights, but not often.

So we are left with an underlying assumption of rational decision making that is not bedrock, but is reasonable and powerful nonetheless. In this chapter, we are going to see what lies behind demand curves by looking at how consumers choose. In the next chapter, we will examine what lies behind supply curves by looking at how producers choose to produce what they do.

There are two major ways to approach consumer choice. The first theory explaining what people choose to buy, given their limited incomes, is known as utility theory or utilitarianism, and owes its roots to the work of 18th-century philosopher Jeremy Bentham. This theory holds that rational consumers will allocate their limited incomes so as to maximize their happiness or satisfaction.

The second approach, indifference curve analysis, is covered in the Appendix. Developed by Francis Ysidro Edgeworth in the late 19th century, it added analytical rigor to utility analysis by developing indifference curves, which portray combinations of two goods of equal total utility. Edgeworth, a shy man who studied in public libraries because he saw material possessions as a burden, brought the precision of mathematics to bear on utility theory.