MARKET STRUCTURE ANALYSIS

196

market structure analysis By observing a few industry characteristics such as number of firms in the industry or the level of barriers to entry, economists can use this information to predict pricing and output behavior of the firm in the industry.

To appreciate competitive markets, we need to look at competition within the full range of possible market structures. Economists use market structure analysis to categorize industries based on a few key characteristics. By knowing simple industry facts, economists can predict the behavior of firms in that industry in such areas as pricing and sales.

Following are the four factors defining the intensity of competition in an industry and a few questions to give you some sense of the issues behind each one of these factors.

Possible market structures range from perfect competition, characterized by many firms, to monopoly, where an industry is made up of only one firm. These market structures will make more sense to you as we consider each one in the chapters ahead. Right now, use this list and the descriptions as reference points. You can always return here and put the discussion in context.

Primary Market Structures

197

The primary market structures economists have identified, along with their key characteristics, are as follows:

image
Perfectly competitive fruit stands in New York City operate in the shadows of large oligopoly financial institutions, adjacent to a city-run bus system (a monopoly), and in front of monopolistically competitive restaurants and shops.
EyeEm/Getty Image

Perfect Competition

Monopolistic Competition

Oligopoly

Monopoly

Putting off discussion of the other market structures for later chapters, we turn to an extended examination of the requirements for a perfectly competitive market. In the remainder of this chapter, we explore short-run pricing and output decisions, and also the importance of entry and exit in the long run. Moreover, we use the conditions of perfect competition to establish a benchmark for efficiency as we turn to evaluate other market structures in the following chapters.

Defining Perfectly Competitive Markets

perfect competition A market structure with many relatively small buyers and sellers who take the price as given, a standardized product, full information to both buyers and sellers, and no barriers to entry or exit.

The theory of perfect competition rests on the following assumptions:

  1. Perfectly competitive markets have many buyers and sellers, each of them so small that none can individually influence product price.

  2. Firms in the industry produce a homogeneous or standardized product.

  3. Buyers and sellers have all the information about prices and product quality they need to make informed decisions.

    198

  4. Barriers to entry or exit are nonexistent; in the long run, new firms are free to enter the industry if doing so appears profitable, while firms are free to exit if they anticipate losses.

price taker Individual firms in perfectly competitive markets determine their prices from the market because they are so small they cannot influence market price. For this reason, perfectly competitive firms are price takers and can sell all the output they produce at market-determined prices.

One implication of these assumptions is that perfectly competitive firms are price takers. Market prices are determined by market forces beyond the control of individual firms. That is, firms must take what they can get for their products. Paper for copy machines, most agricultural products, basic computer memory chips, and many other goods are produced in highly competitive markets. The buyers or sellers in these markets are so small that their ability to influence market price is nonexistent. These firms must accept whatever price the market determines, leaving them to decide only how much of the product to produce or buy.

Panel A of Figure 1 portrays the supply and demand for windsurfing sails in a perfectly competitive market; the market is in equilibrium at a price of $200 per sail and industry output Qe. Remember that this product is a standardized sail (similar to 2 × 4 lumber, corn, or crude oil) and that the market contains many buyers and sellers, who collectively set the product price at $200.

Figure 8.1: FIGURE 1 THE MARKET FOR COMPETITIVE PRODUCTS WITH AN EQUILIBRIUM PRICE OF $200
image
Figure 8.1: Panel A shows a market for standardized windsurfing sails in equilibrium at a price of $200 and industry output Qe. This price is determined by the market’s many buyers and sellers. Panel B illustrates product demand for an individual seller. The individual firm can sell all it wants to at $200 and has no reason to set its price below that. If it tries to sell at prices higher than $200, it sells nothing. The demand curve for the individual firm is horizontal at $200.

Panel B shows the demand for a seller’s products in this market. The firm can sell all it wants at $200 or below. Yet, what firm would set its price below $200 when it can sell everything it produces at $200? Were the firm to set its price above $200, however, it would sell nothing. What consumer, after all, would purchase a standardized sail at a higher price when it can be obtained elsewhere for $200? The individual firm’s demand curve is horizontal at $200. The firm can still determine how much of its product to produce and sell, but this is the only choice it has. The firm cannot set its own price; therefore, it is a price taker.

Recall the profitability equation. Profit equals total revenue minus total cost. Total revenue equals price times quantity sold. In perfectly competitive markets, a firm’s profitability is based on a given market price, quantity sold, and its costs. So how does it determine how much to sell?

The Short Run and the Long Run (A Reminder)

199

Before turning to a more detailed examination of how firms decide how much output to produce in a perfectly competitive market, we need to recall a distinction introduced in the last chapter between the short run and the long run.

In the short run, one factor of production is fixed, usually the firm’s plant size, and firms cannot enter or leave an industry. Thus, in the short run, the number of firms in a market is fixed. Firms may earn economic profits, break even, or suffer losses, but still they cannot exit the industry, nor can new firms enter.

In the long run, all factors are variable, and thus the level of profits induces entry or exit. When losses prevail, some firms will leave the industry and invest their capital elsewhere. When economic profits are positive, new firms will enter the industry. The long run is far more dynamic than the short run.

CHECKPOINT

MARKET STRUCTURE ANALYSIS

  • Market structure analysis allows economists to categorize industries based on a few characteristics and use this analysis to predict pricing and output behavior.

  • The intensity of competition is defined by the number of firms in the industry, the nature of the industry’s product, the level of barriers to entry, and how much firms can control prices.

  • Market structures range from perfect competition (many buyers and sellers), to monopolistic competition (differentiated product), to oligopoly (only a few firms that are interdependent), to monopoly (a one-firm industry).

  • Perfect competition is defined by four attributes: Many buyers and sellers who are so small that none individually can influence price, firms that produce and sell a homogeneous (standardized) product, buyers and sellers who have all the information necessary to make informed decisions, and barriers to entry and exit that are nonexistent.

  • Firms in perfectly competitive markets get the product price from national or global markets. In other words, firms are price takers.

  • In the short run, one factor (usually plant size) is fixed. In the long run, all factors are variable, and firms can enter or leave the industry.

QUESTION: For the following firms, explain where in our market structure approach each firm best fits: Verizon (a wireless communications service provider), NFL (a professional football organization), Grandma’s Southern Kitchen (a small café), Jack’s Lumber (an independent lumber mill).

Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.

Verizon is one of a few major wireless providers in the U.S. market (others include AT&T, T-Mobile, and Sprint). The industry has considerable barriers to entry (e.g., the costs of cellular towers) and is therefore an oligopoly. The NFL is the only major organization for professional football teams, having complete control over all NFL teams nationwide. It also has exclusive contracts with advertisers and television networks. The NFL is best described as a monopoly. Grandma’s Southern Kitchen is one of many restaurants serving southern food, and is differentiated by its location, menu, and quality of food. It is therefore a monopolistically competitive firm. Finally, Jack’s Lumber is one of thousands of lumber mills across the country, each producing a standardized product. It is therefore in a perfectly competitive industry.