Chapter Introduction

327

Export Policies in Resource and High-Technology Industries

This chapter explains the use of export subsidies for resource-based and high-tech industries. It also studies other policies used to in resource-based industries, namely export tariffs and quotas. Finally, it analyzes the use of export subsidies as a form of strategic trade policy in high-tech industries.

  1. WTO Goals on Agricultural Export Subsidies
  2. Export Subsidies in a Small Home Country
  3. Export Subsidies in a Large Home Country
  4. Production Subsidies
  5. Export Tariffs
  6. Export Quotas
  7. High-Technology Export Subsidies
  8. Conclusions

The Middle East has its oil, China has rare earth.

Deng Xiaoping, architect of China’s economic reforms, Southern Tour of China, 1992

After more than a decade, the Doha round of global trade talks finally produced a deal. The package agreed to in Bali on Saturday [December 7, 2013] is significantly less ambitious than what the representatives who convened in [Doha,] Qatar in 2001 had in mind…With developing and rich countries at loggerheads over sensitive topics such as agricultural duties, the World Trade Organization built around a package of “trade facilitation” measures that could be more easily agreed upon.

Financial Times, editorial, December 9, 2013, p.10.

1. Ongoing fierce debate at the WTO about agricultural subsidies: Farmers in the U.S., Europe, Japan, and South Korea benefit from them. However, they lower world prices of agricultural goods. This hurts farmers in land-rich developing countries like Brazil, India, China, and some African countries, but benefits poor developing countries that import agricultural goods.

2. Goals of the Chapter
a. Explain the use of export subsidies in resource-based and high-tech industries: They exist because of political pressure and the desire to support specific social groups. Agricultural subsidies benefit farmers in developed economies, but are expensive and hurt farmers in land-rich developing countries. However, efforts to abolish agricultural subsidies at the WTO have foundered.
b. Explain other policies used in resource-based industries, export tariffs and quotas. Examples: export tariff in Argentina, export quotas on rare-earth minerals in China
c. Examine how governments can use export subsidies strategically to support domestic industries. Example: subsidies to Airbus and Boeing

3. Overall objective: Analyze the effects of export subsidies on prices, trade, and welfare in order to assess arguments for and against their use.

On July 21, 2008, representatives of the 152 countries belonging to the World Trade Organization (WTO) met in Geneva, Switzerland, to discuss reforms of the world trading system. Like earlier meetings in Seattle (1999), Cancún, Mexico (2003), and Hong Kong (2005), this meeting was marked by large-scale protests. Groups including farmers from South Korea and fishermen from the Philippines objected to the impact that agricultural reforms could have on lowering food prices, thereby threatening their livelihoods. Farmers in South Korea, along with those in Japan, Europe, and the United States, benefit from an intricate system of tariffs (taxes on imports) and subsidies (payments to exporters) that keeps prices for their crops high but in some cases lowers prices in the rest of the world. The lower world price hurts farmers in land-rich developing countries such as Brazil, India, China, and some African nations by making it harder for them to export their own agricultural products. On the other hand, the lower world prices are a benefit to land-poor developing countries that must import agricultural products. Consumers in those countries will be hurt if prices end up rising as a result of agricultural reforms in the WTO.

The first goal of this chapter is to explain subsidy policies that affect resource-based industries (such as agriculture, mining, and fuel production) and high-tech industries. The primary reason that countries subsidize exports is political, but there are other reasons as well. For example, agricultural subsidies benefit a group in society (such as farmers) that the government wants to support. Such subsidies occur in the United States, Europe, Japan, South Korea, and many other countries. Because these subsidies are costly to the governments of these countries and because they harm exporters from land-rich developing countries, many countries attending the Doha Round of WTO negotiations (2001–present) advocated for the removal of agricultural subsidies. In exchange for the removal of subsidies, it was expected that land-poor developing countries would lower their tariffs on agricultural goods. This complex negotiation (which involved agriculture in many countries) ultimately failed, and the 2008 Geneva meeting of the Doha Round broke up without agreement. More recently, in December 2013 a much smaller deal to streamline customs procedures was agreed to in Bali, Indonesia, but without agreement on agricultural subsidies, as indicated in the quote at the beginning of the chapter.1 In this chapter, we describe the tentative agreements to reduce agricultural subsidies made at the 2005 Hong Kong meeting of the WTO, and the issues that could not be resolved which led to the breakup of the 2008 Geneva meeting.

328

Police fight rioters outside the World Trade Organization’s meeting. Most of the protesters were South Korean farmers worried about rice imports.
©Lee Jae-Won/Reuters/Corbis

Export subsidies are not the only kind of policy that is used to influence trade in resource-based industries such as agriculture, mining, and fuel extraction. The second goal of this chapter is to explain the effect of two policies, export tariffs and export quotas, on the countries that use them. To raise government revenue, some countries impose export tariffs, taxes applied by the exporting country when a good leaves the country.2 Argentina, for example, charges export tariffs on many agricultural and resource exports. In 2011 the tariffs were 35% on soybeans, 30% on sunflower meal and oil, 23% on wheat, 20% on corn, and 20% on biodiesel (vegetable oil–based diesel fuel). Another trade policy that can sometimes benefit companies is an export quota, a restriction on the amount that producers are allowed to export. China, for example, applied quotas on firms exporting “rare earth” minerals in 2011 and 2012, which led to a substantial increase in the price of these minerals.

The third goal of the chapter is to examine how governments can strategically use export subsidies to bolster domestic companies and industries. Instead of being used to support a particular industry or to raise revenue for the government, some subsidies are meant to give a domestic industry a strategic advantage in international competition. Some high-technology industries, such as Airbus in Europe and Boeing in the United States, receive generous government subsidies, which often leads to political friction. Legislators often believe that subsidies to high-tech industries will raise those industries’ profits and benefit the exporting country.

In this chapter, we assess the arguments for and against the various export policies by examining their effects on prices, the amount of trade, and welfare.

329