Investment Spending

Although consumer spending is much greater than investment spending, booms and busts in investment spending tend to drive the business cycle. In fact, most recessions originate as a fall in investment spending. Figure 16.4 illustrates this point; it shows the annual percentage change of investment spending and consumer spending in the United States, both measured in 2005 dollars, during six recessions from 1973 to 2009. As you can see, swings in investment spending are much more dramatic than those in consumer spending. In addition, economists believe that declines in consumer spending are usually the result of slumps in investment spending that trigger the spending multiplier process. Soon we’ll examine in more detail how investment spending affects consumer spending.

image
Figure 16.4: Fluctuations in Investment Spending and Consumer SpendingThe bars illustrate the annual percent change in investment spending and consumer spending during six recent recessions. As the heights of the bars show, swings in investment spending were much larger in percentage terms than those in consumer spending. The pattern has led economists to believe that recessions typically originate as a slump in investment spending.

Planned investment spending is the investment spending that businesses intend to undertake during a given period.

Before we do that, however, let’s analyze the factors that determine investment spending, which are somewhat different from those that determine consumer spending. Planned investment spending is the investment spending that firms intend to undertake during a given period. For reasons explained shortly, the level of investment spending that businesses actually carry out is sometimes not the same level as was planned. Planned investment spending depends on three principal factors: the interest rate, the expected future level of real GDP, and the current level of production capacity. First, we’ll analyze the effect of the interest rate.

The Interest Rate and Investment Spending

167

Interest rates have their clearest effect on one particular form of investment spending: spending on residential construction—that is, on the construction of homes. The reason is straightforward: home builders only build houses they think they can sell, and houses are more affordable—and so more likely to sell—when the interest rate is low. Consider a potential home-buying family that needs to borrow $150,000 to buy a house. At an interest rate of 7.5%, a 30-year home mortgage will mean payments of $1,048 per month. At an interest rate of 5.5%, those payments would be only $851 per month, making houses significantly more affordable. Interest rates actually did drop from roughly 7.5% to 5.5% between the late 1990s and 2003, helping set off a housing boom.

Interest rates also affect other forms of investment spending. Firms with investment spending projects will go ahead with a project only if they expect a rate of return higher than the cost of the funds they would have to borrow to finance that project. If the interest rate rises, fewer projects will pass that test, and, as a result, investment spending will be lower.

image
Interest rates have a direct impact on whether or not construction companies decide to invest in the construction of new homes.
Dmitry Kalinovsky/Shutterstock

You might think that the trade-off a firm faces is different if it can fund its investment project with its past profits rather than through borrowing. Past profits used to finance investment spending are called retained earnings. But even if a firm pays for investment spending out of retained earnings, the trade-off it must make in deciding whether or not to fund a project remains the same because it must take into account the opportunity cost of its funds. For example, instead of purchasing new equipment, the firm could lend out the funds and earn interest. The forgone interest earned is the opportunity cost of using retained earnings to fund an investment project. So the trade-off the firm faces when comparing a project’s rate of return to the market interest rate has not changed when it uses retained earnings rather than borrowed funds. Either way, a rise in the market interest rate makes any given investment project less profitable. Conversely, a fall in the interest rate makes some investment projects that were unprofitable before profitable at the new lower interest rate. As a result, some projects that had been unfunded before will be funded now.

So planned investment spending—spending on investment projects that firms voluntarily decide whether or not to undertake—is negatively related to the interest rate. Other things equal, a higher interest rate leads to a lower level of planned investment spending.

Expected Future Real GDP, Production Capacity, and Investment Spending

Suppose a firm has enough capacity to continue to produce the amount it is currently selling but doesn’t expect its sales to grow in the future. Then it will engage in investment spending only to replace existing equipment and structures that wear out or are rendered obsolete by new technologies. But if, instead, the firm expects its sales to grow rapidly in the future, it will find its existing production capacity insufficient for its future production needs. So the firm will undertake investment spending to meet those needs. This implies that, other things equal, firms will undertake more investment spending when they expect their sales to grow.

Now suppose that the firm currently has considerably more capacity than necessary to meet current production needs. Even if it expects sales to grow, it won’t have to undertake investment spending for a while—not until the growth in sales catches up with its excess capacity. This illustrates the fact that, other things equal, the current level of productive capacity has a negative effect on investment spending: other things equal, the higher the current capacity, the lower the investment spending.

168

If we put together the effects on investment spending of (1) growth in expected future sales and (2) the size of current production capacity, we can see one situation in which firms will most likely undertake high levels of investment spending: when they expect sales to grow rapidly. In that case, even excess production capacity will soon be used up, leading firms to resume investment spending.

What is an indicator of high expected growth in future sales? It’s a high expected future growth rate of real GDP. A higher expected future growth rate of real GDP results in a higher level of planned investment spending, but a lower expected future growth rate of real GDP leads to lower planned investment spending.

Inventories and Unplanned Investment Spending

AP® Exam Tip

An increase in unplanned inventories is preceded by a decrease in consumer spending. A decrease in unplanned inventories is preceded by an increase in consumer spending.

Most firms maintain inventories, stocks of goods held to satisfy future sales. Firms hold inventories so they can quickly satisfy buyers—a consumer can purchase an item off the shelf rather than waiting for it to be manufactured. In addition, businesses often hold inventories of their inputs to be sure they have a steady supply of necessary materials and spare parts. At the end of 2013, the overall value of inventories in the U.S. economy was estimated at $2.5 trillion, more than 14% of GDP.

A firm that increases its inventories is engaging in a form of investment spending. Suppose, for example, that the U.S. auto industry produces 800,000 cars per month but sells only 700,000. The remaining 100,000 cars are added to the inventory at auto company warehouses or car dealerships, ready to be sold in the future.

Inventory investment is the value of the change in total inventories held in the economy during a given period.

Inventory investment is the value of the change in total inventories held in the economy during a given period. Unlike other forms of investment spending, inventory investment can actually be negative. If, for example, the auto industry reduces its inventory over the course of a month, we say that it has engaged in negative inventory investment.

Positive unplanned inventory investment occurs when actual sales are lower than businesses expected, leading to unplanned increases in inventories. Sales in excess of expectations result in negative unplanned inventory investment.

Actual investment spending is the sum of planned investment spending and unplanned inventory investment.

To understand inventory investment, think about a manager stocking the canned goods section of a supermarket. The manager tries to keep the store fully stocked so that shoppers can almost always find what they’re looking for. But the manager does not want the shelves too heavily stocked because shelf space is limited and products can spoil. Similar considerations apply to many firms and typically lead them to manage their inventories carefully. However, sales fluctuate. And because firms cannot always accurately predict sales, they often find themselves holding larger or smaller inventories than they had intended. When a firm’s inventories are higher than intended due to an unforeseen decrease in sales, the result is unplanned inventory investment. An unexpected increase in sales depletes inventories and causes the value of unplanned inventory investment to be negative.

image
Getty Images

So in any given period, actual investment spending is equal to planned investment spending plus unplanned inventory investment. If we let IUnplanned represent unplanned inventory investment, IPlanned represent planned investment spending, and I represent actual investment spending, then the relationship among all three can be represented as:

image

To see how unplanned inventory investment can occur, let’s continue to focus on the auto industry and make the following assumptions. First, let’s assume that the industry must determine each month’s production volume in advance, before it knows the volume of actual sales. Second, let’s assume that it anticipates selling 800,000 cars next month and that it plans neither to add to nor subtract from existing inventories. In that case, it will produce 800,000 cars to match anticipated sales.

169

Interest Rates and the U.S. Housing Boom

Interest rates in the United States dropped from roughly 7.5% to 5.5% between the late 1990s and 2003, helping set off a nationwide housing boom. There is little question that this housing boom was caused, in the first instance, by low interest rates.

The figure below shows the interest rate on 30-year home mortgages—the traditional way to borrow money for a home purchase—and the number of housing starts—the number of homes for which construction is started per month—from 1995 to the end of 2013 in the United States. Panel (a), which shows the mortgage rate, gives you an idea of how much interest rates fell. In the second half of the 1990s, mortgage rates generally fluctuated between 7% and 8%; by 2003, they were down to between 5% and 6%. These lower rates were largely the result of Federal Reserve policy: the Fed cut rates in response to the 2001 recession and continued cutting them into 2003 out of concern that the economy’s recovery was too weak to generate sustained job growth.

The low interest rates led to a large increase in residential investment spending, reflected in a surge of housing starts, shown in panel (b). This rise in investment spending drove an overall economic expansion, both through its direct effects and through the spending multiplier process.

Unfortunately, the housing boom eventually turned into too much of a good thing. By 2006, it was clear that the U.S. housing market was experiencing a bubble: people were buying housing based on unrealistic expectations about future price increases. When the bubble burst, housing—and the U.S. economy—took a fall. The fall was so severe that, even when the Fed cut interest rates to near zero and mortgage rates consequently dropped to below 5% beginning in 2009, housing starts merely stabilized. As of early 2014, housing starts had not yet fully recovered.

image
Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Now imagine that next month’s actual sales are less than expected, only 700,000 cars. As a result, the value of 100,000 cars will be added to investment spending as unplanned inventory investment.

The auto industry will, of course, eventually adjust to this slowdown in sales and the resulting unplanned inventory investment. It is likely that it will cut next month’s production volume in order to reduce inventories. In fact, economists who study macroeconomic variables in an attempt to determine the future path of the economy pay careful attention to changes in inventory levels. Rising inventories typically indicate positive unplanned inventory investment and a slowing economy, as sales are less than had been forecast. Falling inventories typically indicate negative unplanned inventory investment and a growing economy, as sales are greater than forecast. In the next section, we will see how production adjustments in response to fluctuations in sales and inventories ensure that the value of final goods and services actually produced is equal to desired purchases of those final goods and services.