The National Accounts

Almost all countries calculate a set of numbers known as the national income and product accounts. In fact, the accuracy of a country’s accounts is a remarkably reliable indicator of its state of economic development—in general, the more reliable the accounts, the more economically advanced the country. When international economic agencies seek to help a less developed country, typically the first order of business is to send a team of experts to audit and improve the country’s accounts.

The national income and product accounts, or national accounts, keep track of the flows of money between different sectors of the economy.

In the United States, these numbers are calculated by the Bureau of Economic Analysis, a division of the U.S. government’s Department of Commerce. The national income and product accounts, often referred to simply as the national accounts, keep track of the spending of consumers, sales of producers, business investment spending, government purchases, and a variety of other flows of money between different sectors of the economy. Let’s see how they work.

The Circular-Flow Diagram, Revisited and Expanded

To understand the principles behind the national accounts, it helps to look at Figure 22-1, a revised and expanded circular-flow diagram similar to the one we introduced in Chapter 2. Recall that in Figure 2-6 we showed the flows of money, goods and services, and factors of production through the economy. Here we restrict ourselves to flows of money but add extra elements that allow us to show the key concepts behind the national accounts. As in our original version of the circular-flow diagram, the underlying principle is that the inflow of money into each market or sector is equal to the outflow of money coming from that market or sector.

An Expanded Circular-Flow Diagram: The Flows of Money Through the Economy A circular flow of funds connects the four sectors of the economy—households, firms, government, and the rest of the world—via three types of markets: the factor markets, the markets for goods and services, and the financial markets. Funds flow from firms to households in the form of wages, profit, interest, and rent through the factor markets. After paying taxes to the government and receiving government transfers, households allocate the remaining income—disposable income—to private savings and consumer spending. Via the financial markets, private savings and funds from the rest of the world are channeled into investment spending by firms, government borrowing, foreign borrowing and lending, and foreign transactions of stocks. In turn, funds flow from the government and households to firms to pay for purchases of goods and services. Finally, exports to the rest of the world generate a flow of funds into the economy and imports lead to a flow of funds out of the economy. If we add up consumer spending on goods and services, investment spending by firms, government purchases of goods and services, and exports, then subtract the value of imports, the total flow of funds represented by this calculation is total spending on final goods and services produced in the United States. Equivalently, it’s the value of all the final goods and services produced in the United States—that is, the gross domestic product of the economy.

Consumer spending is household spending on goods and services.

Figure 2-6 showed a simplified world containing only two kinds of “inhabitants,” households and firms. And it illustrated the circular flow of money between households and firms, which remains visible in Figure 22-1. In the markets for goods and services, households engage in consumer spending, buying goods and services from domestic firms and from firms in the rest of the world.

Households also own factors of production—labor, land, physical capital, human capital, and financial capital. They sell the use of these factors of production to firms, receiving wages, profit, interest payments, and rent in return. Firms buy and pay households for the use of those factors of production in the factor markets. Most households derive the bulk of their income from wages earned by selling labor and human capital.

A stock is a share in the ownership of a company held by a shareholder.

But households derive additional income from their indirect ownership of the physical capital used by firms, mainly in the form of stocks, shares in the ownership of a company, and from direct ownership of bonds, borrowing by firms in the form of an IOU that pays interest. So the income households receive from the factor markets includes profits distributed to shareholders known as dividends, and the interest payments on bonds held by bondholders. Finally, households receive rent in return for allowing firms to use land or structures that they own. So households receive income in the form of wages, profit, interest payments, and rent via factor markets.

A bond is borrowing in the form of an IOU that pays interest.

In our original, simplified circular-flow diagram, households spent all the income they received via factor markets on goods and services. Figure 22-1, however, illustrates a more complicated but more realistic diagram. There we see two reasons why goods and services don’t in fact absorb all of households’ income.

Government transfers are payments by the government to individuals for which no good or service is provided in return.

First, households don’t get to keep all the income they receive via the factor markets. They must pay part of their income to the government in the form of taxes, such as income taxes and sales taxes. In addition, some households receive government transfers—payments by the government to individuals for which no good or service is provided in return, such as Social Security benefits and unemployment insurance payments. The total income households have left after paying taxes and receiving government transfers is disposable income.

Disposable income, equal to income plus government transfers minus taxes, is the total amount of household income available to spend on consumption and to save.

Private savings, equal to disposable income minus consumer spending, is disposable income that is not spent on consumption.

Second, households normally don’t spend all of their disposable income on goods and services. Instead, a portion of their income is typically set aside as private savings, which goes into financial markets where individuals, banks, and other institutions buy and sell stocks and bonds as well as make loans. As Figure 22-1 shows, the financial markets also receive funds from the rest of the world and provide funds to the government, to firms, and to the rest of the world.

The banking, stock, and bond markets, which channel private savings and foreign lending into investment spending, government borrowing, and foreign borrowing, are known as the financial markets.

Before going further, we can use the box representing households to illustrate an important general feature of the circular-flow diagram: the total sum of flows of money out of a given box is equal to the total sum of flows of money into that box. It’s simply a matter of accounting: what goes in must come out. So, for example, the total flow of money out of households—the sum of taxes paid, consumer spending, and private savings—must equal the total flow of money into households—the sum of wages, profits, interest payments, rent, and government transfers.

Government borrowing is the total amount of funds borrowed by federal, state, and local governments in the financial markets.

Now let’s look at the other types of inhabitants we’ve added to the circular-flow diagram, including the government—all federal, state, and local governments—and the rest of the world. The government returns a portion of the money it collects from taxes to households in the form of government transfers. However, it uses much of its tax revenue, plus additional funds borrowed in the financial markets through government borrowing, to buy goods and services. Government purchases of goods and services, the total purchases by federal, state, and local governments, include everything from military spending on ammunition to your local public school’s spending on chalk, erasers, and teacher salaries.

Government purchases of goods and services are total expenditures on goods and services by federal, state, and local governments.

Goods and services sold to other countries are exports. Goods and services purchased from other countries are imports.

The rest of the world participates in the U.S. economy in three ways.

  1. Some of the goods and services produced in the United States are sold to residents of other countries. For example, more than half of America’s annual wheat and cotton crops are sold abroad. Goods and services sold to other countries are known as exports. Export sales lead to a flow of funds from the rest of the world into the United States to pay for them.

  2. Some of the goods and services purchased by residents of the United States are produced abroad. For example, many consumer goods are now made in China. Goods and services purchased from residents of other countries are known as imports. Import purchases lead to a flow of funds out of the United States to pay for them.

  3. Foreigners can participate in U.S. financial markets by making transactions. Foreign lending—lending by foreigners to borrowers in the United States, and purchases by foreigners of shares of stock in American companies—generates a flow of funds into the United States from the rest of the world. Conversely, foreign borrowing—borrowing by foreigners from U.S. lenders and purchases by Americans of stock in foreign companies—leads to a flow of funds out of the United States to the rest of the world.

Finally, let’s go back to the markets for goods and services. In Chapter 2 we focused only on purchases of goods and services by households. We now see that there are other types of spending on goods and services, including government purchases, investment spending by firms, imports, and exports.

Inventories are stocks of goods and raw materials held to facilitate business operations.

Notice that firms also buy goods and services in our expanded economy. For example, an automobile company that is building a new factory will buy investment goods—machinery like stamping presses and welding robots that are used to produce goods and services for consumers—from companies that manufacture these items. It will also accumulate an inventory of finished cars in preparation for shipment to dealers. Inventories, then, are stocks of goods and raw materials that firms hold to facilitate their operations. The national accounts count this investment spending—spending on productive physical capital, such as machinery and construction of buildings, and on changes to inventories—as part of total spending on goods and services.

Investment spending is spending on productive physical capital—such as machinery and construction of buildings—and on changes to inventories.

You might ask why changes to inventories are included in investment spending—finished cars aren’t, after all, used to produce more cars. Changes to inventories of finished goods are counted as investment spending because, like machinery, they change the ability of a firm to make future sales. So spending on additions to inventories is a form of investment spending by a firm. Conversely, a drawing-down of inventories is counted as a fall in investment spending because it leads to lower future sales.

It’s also important to understand that investment spending includes spending on construction of any structure, regardless of whether it is an assembly plant or a new house. Why include construction of homes? Because, like a plant, a new house produces a future stream of output—housing services for its occupants.

Suppose we add up consumer spending on goods and services, investment spending, government purchases of goods and services, and the value of exports, then subtract the value of imports. This gives us a measure of the overall market value of the goods and services the economy produces. That measure has a name: it’s a country’s gross domestic product. But before we can formally define gross domestic product, or GDP, we have to examine an important distinction between classes of goods and services: the difference between final goods and services versus intermediate goods and services.

Gross Domestic Product

Final goods and services are goods and services sold to the final, or end, user.

A consumer’s purchase of a new car from a dealer is one example of a sale of final goods and services: goods and services sold to the final, or end, user. But an automobile manufacturer’s purchase of steel from a steel foundry or glass from a glassmaker is an example of purchasing intermediate goods and services: goods and services that are inputs for production of final goods and services. In the case of intermediate goods and services, the purchaser—another firm—is not the final user.

Intermediate goods and services are goods and services—bought from one firm by another firm—that are inputs for production of final goods and services.

Gross domestic product, or GDP, is the total value of all final goods and services produced in the economy during a given year.

Gross domestic product, or GDP, is the total value of all final goods and services produced in an economy during a given period, usually a year. In 2013 the GDP of the United States was $16,800 billion, or about $53,000 per person. If you are an economist trying to construct a country’s national accounts, one way to calculate GDP is to calculate it directly: survey firms and add up the total value of their production of final goods and services. We’ll explain in detail in the next section why intermediate goods, and some other types of goods as well, are not included in the calculation of GDP.

But adding up the total value of final goods and services produced isn’t the only way of calculating GDP. There is another way, based on total spending on final goods and services. Since GDP is equal to the total value of final goods and services produced in the economy, it must also equal the flow of funds received by firms from sales in the goods and services market.

Aggregate spending, the sum of consumer spending, investment spending, government purchases of goods and services, and exports minus imports, is the total spending on domestically produced final goods and services in the economy.

If you look again at the circular-flow diagram in Figure 22-1, you will see that the arrow going from markets for goods and services to firms is indeed labeled “Gross domestic product.” According to our basic rule of accounting, flows out of any box are equal to flows into the box; so the flow of funds out of the markets for goods and services to firms is equal to the total flow of funds into the markets for goods and services from other sectors. And as you can see from Figure 22-1, the total flow of funds into the markets for goods and services is total or aggregate spending on domestically produced final goods and services—the sum of consumer spending, investment spending, government purchases of goods and services, and exports minus imports. So a second way of calculating GDP is to add up aggregate spending on domestically produced final goods and services in the economy.

And there is yet a third way of calculating GDP, based on total income earned in the economy. Firms, and the factors of production that they employ, are owned by households. So firms must ultimately pay out what they earn to households. The flow from firms to the factor markets is the factor income paid out by firms to households in the form of wages, profit, interest, and rent. Again, by accounting rules, the value of the flow of factor income from firms to households must be equal to the flow of money into firms from the markets for goods and services. And this last value, we know, is the total value of production in the economy—GDP.

Why is GDP equal to the total value of factor income paid by firms in the economy to households? Because each sale in the economy must accrue to someone as income—either as wages, profit, interest, or rent. So a third way of calculating GDP is to sum the total factor income earned by households from firms in the economy.

Calculating GDP

We’ve just explained that there are in fact three methods for calculating GDP:

  1. adding up total value of all final goods and services produced

  2. adding up spending on all domestically produced goods and services

  3. adding up total factor income earned by households from firms in the economy

Government statisticians use all three methods. To illustrate how these three methods work, we will consider a hypothetical economy, shown in Figure 22-2. This economy consists of three firms—American Motors, Inc., which produces one car per year; American Steel, Inc., which produces the steel that goes into the car; and American Ore, Inc., which mines the iron ore that goes into the steel. So GDP is $21,500, the value of the one car per year the economy produces. Let’s look at how the three different methods of calculating GDP yield the same result.

Calculating GDP In this hypothetical economy consisting of three firms, GDP can be calculated in three different ways: 1) measuring GDP as the value of production of final goods and services, by summing each firm’s value added; 2) measuring GDP as aggregate spending on domestically produced final goods and services; and 3) measuring GDP as factor income earned by households from firms in the economy.

Measuring GDP as the Value of Production of Final Goods and Services The first method for calculating GDP is to add up the value of all the final goods and services produced in the economy—a calculation that excludes the value of intermediate goods and services. Why are intermediate goods and services excluded? After all, don’t they represent a very large and valuable portion of the economy?

To understand why only final goods and services are included in GDP, look at the simplified economy described in Figure 22-2. Should we measure the GDP of this economy by adding up the total sales of the iron ore producer, the steel producer, and the auto producer? If we did, we would in effect be counting the value of the steel twice—once when it is sold by the steel plant to the auto plant, and again when the steel auto body is sold to a consumer as a finished car. And we would be counting the value of the iron ore three times—once when it is mined and sold to the steel company, a second time when it is made into steel and sold to the auto producer, and a third time when the steel is made into a car and sold to the consumer.

The value added of a producer is the value of its sales minus the value of its purchases of intermediate goods and services.

So counting the full value of each producer’s sales would cause us to count the same items several times and artificially inflate the calculation of GDP. For example, in Figure 22-2, the total value of all sales, intermediate and final, is $34,700: $21,500 from the sale of the car, plus $9,000 from the sale of the steel, plus $4,200 from the sale of the iron ore. Yet we know that GDP is only $21,500. The way we avoid double-counting is to count only each producer’s value added in the calculation of GDP: the difference between the value of its sales and the value of the intermediate goods and services it purchases from other businesses.

That is, we subtract the cost of inputs—the intermediate goods—at each stage of the production process. In this case, the value added of the auto producer is the dollar value of the cars it manufactures minus the cost of the steel it buys, or $12,500. The value added of the steel producer is the dollar value of the steel it produces minus the cost of the ore it buys, or $4,800. Only the ore producer, which we have assumed doesn’t buy any inputs, has value added equal to its total sales, $4,200. The sum of the three producers’ value added is $21,500, equal to GDP.

Steel is an intermediate good because it is sold to other product manufacturers like automakers, and rarely to final buyers, such as consumers.

Measuring GDP as Spending on Domestically Produced Final Goods and Services Another way to calculate GDP is by adding up aggregate spending on domestically produced final goods and services. That is, GDP can be measured by the flow of funds into firms. Like the method that estimates GDP as the value of domestic production of final goods and services, this measurement must be carried out in a way that avoids double-counting.

In terms of our steel and auto example, we don’t want to count both consumer spending on a car (represented in Figure 22-2 by $12,500, the sales price of the car) and the auto producer’s spending on steel (represented in Figure 22-2 by $9,000, the price of a car’s worth of steel). If we counted both, we would be counting the steel embodied in the car twice. We solve this problem by counting only the value of sales to final buyers, such as consumers, firms that purchase investment goods, the government, or foreign buyers. In other words, in order to avoid double-counting of spending, we omit sales of inputs from one business to another when estimating GDP using spending data. You can see from Figure 22-2 that aggregate spending on final goods and services—the finished car—is $21,500.

FOR INQUIRING MINDS: Our Imputed Lives

The value of the services that family members provide to each other is not counted as part of GDP.

An old line says that when a person marries the household cook, GDP falls. And it’s true: when someone provides services for pay, those services are counted as a part of GDP. But the services family members provide to each other are not. Some economists have produced alternative measures that try to “impute” the value of household work—that is, assign an estimate of what the market value of that work would have been if it had been paid for. But the standard measure of GDP doesn’t contain that imputation.

GDP estimates do, however, include an imputation for the value of “owner-occupied housing.” That is, if you buy the home you were formerly renting, GDP does not go down. It’s true that because you no longer pay rent to your landlord, the landlord no longer sells a service to you—namely, use of the house or apartment. But the statisticians make an estimate of what you would have paid if you rented whatever you live in, whether it’s an apartment or a house. For the purposes of the statistics, it’s as if you were renting your dwelling from yourself.

If you think about it, this makes a lot of sense. In a home-owning country like the United States, the pleasure we derive from our houses is an important part of the standard of living. So to be accurate, estimates of GDP must take into account the value of housing that is occupied by owners as well as the value of rental housing.

As we’ve already pointed out, the national accounts do include investment spending by firms as a part of final spending. That is, an auto company’s purchase of steel to make a car isn’t considered a part of final spending, but the company’s purchase of new machinery for its factory is considered a part of final spending. What’s the difference? Steel is an input that is used up in production; machinery will last for a number of years. Since purchases of capital goods that will last for a considerable time aren’t closely tied to current production, the national accounts consider such purchases a form of final sales.

In later chapters, we will make use of the proposition that GDP is equal to aggregate spending on domestically produced goods and services by final buyers. We will also develop models of how final buyers decide how much to spend. With that in mind, we’ll now examine the types of spending that make up GDP.

Look again at the markets for goods and services in Figure 22-1, and you will see that one component of sales by firms is consumer spending. Let’s denote consumer spending with the symbol C. Figure 22-1 also shows three other components of sales: sales of investment goods to other businesses, or investment spending, which we will denote by I; government purchases of goods and services, which we will denote by G; and sales to foreigners—that is, exports—which we will denote by X.

In reality, not all of this final spending goes toward domestically produced goods and services. We must take account of spending on imports, which we will denote by IM. Income spent on imports is income not spent on domestic goods and services—it is income that has “leaked” across national borders. So to accurately value domestic production using spending data, we must subtract out spending on imports to arrive at spending on domestically produced goods and services. Putting this all together gives us the following equation that breaks GDP down by the four sources of aggregate spending:

We’ll be seeing a lot of Equation 22-1 in later chapters.

PITFALLS

PITFALLS: GDP: WHAT’S IN AND WHAT’S OUT

GDP: WHAT’S IN AND WHAT’S OUT
It’s easy to confuse what is included in and what is excluded from GDP. So let’s stop here for a moment and make sure the distinction is clear. The most likely source of confusion is the difference between investment spending and spending on intermediate goods and services. Investment spending—spending on productive physical capital (including construction of residential and commercial structures), and changes to inventories—is included in GDP. But spending on intermediate goods and services is not.

Why the difference? Recall from Chapter 2 that we made a distinction between resources that are used up and those that are not used up in production. An input, like steel, is used up in production. An investment good, like a metal-stamping machine, is not. It will last for many years and will be used repeatedly to make many cars. Since spending on productive physical capital—investment goods—and construction of structures is not directly tied to current output, economists consider such spending to be spending on final goods.

Spending on changes to inventories is considered a part of investment spending, so it is also included in GDP. Why? Because, like a machine, additional inventory is an investment in future sales. And when a good is released for sale from inventories, its value is subtracted from the value of inventories and so from GDP.

Used goods are not included in GDP because, as with inputs, to include them would be to double-count: counting them once when sold as new and again when sold as used.

Also, financial assets such as stocks and bonds are not included in GDP because they don’t represent either the production or the sale of final goods and services. Rather, a bond represents a promise to repay with interest, and a stock represents a proof of ownership. And for obvious reasons, foreign-produced goods and services are not included in calculations of GDP.

Here is a summary of what’s included and not included in GDP:

Included

  • Domestically produced final goods and services, including capital goods, new construction of structures, and changes to inventories

Not Included

  • Intermediate goods and services

  • Inputs

  • Used goods

  • Financial assets like stocks and bonds

  • Foreign-produced goods and services

Measuring GDP as Factor Income Earned from Firms in the Economy A final way to calculate GDP is to add up all the income earned by factors of production from firms in the economy—the wages earned by labor; the interest paid to those who lend their savings to firms and the government; the rent earned by those who lease their land or structures to firms; and dividends, the profits paid to the shareholders, the owners of the firms’ physical capital. This is a valid measure because the money firms earn by selling goods and services must go somewhere; whatever isn’t paid as wages, interest, or rent is profit. Ultimately, profits are paid out to shareholders as dividends.

Figure 22-2 shows how this calculation works for our simplified economy. The numbers shaded in the column at far right show the total wages, interest, and rent paid by all these firms as well as their total profit. Summing up all of these items yields total factor income of $21,500—again, equal to GDP.

We won’t emphasize factor income as much as the other two methods of calculating GDP. It’s important to keep in mind, however, that all the money spent on domestically produced goods and services generates factor income to households—that is, there really is a circular flow.

The Components of GDP Now that we know how GDP is calculated in principle, let’s see what it looks like in practice.

Figure 22-3 shows the first two methods of calculating GDP side by side. The height of each bar above the horizontal axis represents the GDP of the U.S. economy in 2013: $16,800 billion. Each bar is divided to show the breakdown of that total in terms of where the value was added and how the money was spent.

U.S. GDP in 2013: Two Methods of Calculating GDP The two bars show two equivalent ways of calculating GDP. The height of each bar above the horizontal axis represents $16,800 billion, U.S. GDP in 2013. The left bar shows the breakdown of GDP according to the value added of each sector of the economy: government, households, and firms. The right bar shows the breakdown of GDP according to the four types of aggregate spending: C + I + G + XIM. The right bar has a total length of $16,800 billion + $497 billion = $17,297 billion. The $497 billion, shown as the area extending below the horizontal axis, is the amount of total spending absorbed by net exports, which were negative in 2013. (Numbers don’t add due to rounding.)Source: Bureau of Economic Analysis.

In the left bar in Figure 22-3, we see the breakdown of GDP by value added according to sector, the first method of calculating GDP. Of the $16,800 billion, $12,684 billion consisted of value added by businesses. Another $2,079 billion of value added was added by households and institutions; a large part of that was the imputed services of owner-occupied housing, described in the earlier For Inquiring Minds “Our Imputed Lives.” Finally, $2,036 billion consisted of value added by government, in the form of military, education, and other government services.

The right bar in Figure 22-3 corresponds to the second method of calculating GDP, showing the breakdown by the four types of aggregate spending. The total length of the right bar is longer than the total length of the left bar, a difference of $497 billion (which, as you can see, is the amount by which the right bar extends below the horizontal axis). That’s because the total length of the right bar represents total spending in the economy, spending on both domestically produced and foreign-produced final goods and services. Within the bar, consumer spending (C), which is 68.4% of GDP, dominates overall spending.

Net exports are the difference between the value of exports and the value of imports.

But some of that spending was absorbed by foreign-produced goods and services. In 2013, net exports, the difference between the value of exports and the value of imports (XIM in Equation 22-1) was negative—the United States was a net importer of foreign goods and services. The 2013 value of XIM was −$497 billion, or −3.0% of GDP. Thus, a portion of the right bar extends below the horizontal axis by $497 billion to represent the amount of total spending that was absorbed by net imports and so did not lead to higher U.S. GDP. Investment spending (I) constituted 15.9% of GDP; government purchases of goods and services (G) constituted 18.6% of GDP.

!worldview! FOR INQUIRING MINDS: Gross What?

Occasionally you may see references not to gross domestic product but to gross national product, or GNP. Is this just another name for the same thing? Not quite.

If you look at Figure 22-1 carefully, you may realize that there’s a possibility that is missing from the figure. According to the figure, all factor income goes to domestic households. But what happens when profits are paid to foreigners who own stock in General Motors or Apple? And where do the profits earned by American companies operating overseas fit in?

To answer these questions, an alternative measure, GNP, was devised. GNP is defined as the total factor income earned by residents of a country. It excludes factor income earned by foreigners, like profits paid to foreign investors who own American stocks and payments to foreigners who work temporarily in the United States. And it includes factor income earned abroad by Americans, like the profits of Apple’s European operations that accrue to Apple’s American shareholders and the wages of Americans who work abroad temporarily.

GNP, the value of output produced within a country’s borders, typically differs from GDP, the value of output produced worldwide that is owned by a country’s citizens and firms.

In the early days of national income accounting, economists usually used GNP rather than GDP as a measure of the economy’s size—although the measures were generally very close to each other. They switched to GDP mainly because it’s considered a better indicator of short-run movements in production and because data on international flows of factor income are considered somewhat unreliable.

In practice, it doesn’t make much difference which measure is used for large economies like that of the United States, where the flows of net factor income to other countries are relatively small. In 2013, America’s GNP was about 1.5% larger than its GDP, mainly because of the overseas profit of U.S. companies. However, for smaller countries, which are likely to be hosts to a number of foreign companies, GDP and GNP can diverge significantly. For example, much of Ireland’s industry is owned by American corporations, whose profit must be deducted from Ireland’s GNP. In addition, Ireland has become a host to many temporary workers from poorer regions of Europe, whose wages must also be deducted from Ireland’s GNP. As a result, in 2013 Ireland’s GNP was only 86% of its GDP.

What GDP Tells Us

Now we’ve seen the various ways that gross domestic product is calculated. But what does the measurement of GDP tell us?

The most important use of GDP is as a measure of the size of the economy, providing us a scale against which to measure the economic performance of other years or to compare the economic performance of other countries. For example, suppose you want to compare the economies of different nations. A natural approach is to compare their GDPs. In 2013, as we’ve seen, U.S. GDP was $16,800 billion, China’s GDP was $9,181 billion, and the combined GDP of the 27 countries that make up the European Union was $17,371 billion. This comparison tells us that China, although it has the world’s second-largest national economy, carries considerably less economic weight than does the United States. When taken in aggregate, Europe is America’s equal or superior.

Still, one must be careful when using GDP numbers, especially when making comparisons over time. That’s because part of the increase in the value of GDP over time represents increases in the prices of goods and services rather than an increase in output. For example, U.S. GDP was $8,608 billion in 1997 and had approximately doubled to $16,800 billion by 2013. But the U.S. economy didn’t actually double in size over that period. To measure actual changes in aggregate output, we need a modified version of GDP that is adjusted for price changes, known as real GDP. We’ll see next how real GDP is calculated.

ECONOMICS in Action: Creating the National Accounts

Creating the National Accounts

The national accounts, like modern macroeconomics, owe their creation to the Great Depression. As the economy plunged into depression, government officials found their ability to respond crippled not only by the lack of adequate economic theories but also by the lack of adequate information. All they had were scattered statistics: railroad freight car loadings, stock prices, and incomplete indexes of industrial production. They could only guess at what was happening to the economy as a whole.

In response to this perceived lack of information, the Department of Commerce commissioned Simon Kuznets, a young Russian-born economist, to develop a set of national income accounts. (Kuznets later won the Nobel Prize in economics for his work.) The first version of these accounts was presented to Congress in 1937 and in a research report titled National Income, 1929–35.

Kuznets’s initial estimates fell short of the full modern set of accounts because they focused on income, not production. The push to complete the national accounts came during World War II, when policy makers were in even more need of comprehensive measures of the economy’s performance. The federal government began issuing estimates of gross domestic product and gross national product in 1942.

In January 2000, in its publication Survey of Current Business, the Department of Commerce ran an article titled “GDP: One of the Great Inventions of the 20th Century.” This may seem a bit over the top, but national income accounting, invented in the United States, has since become a tool of economic analysis and policy making around the world.

Quick Review

  • A country’s national income and product accounts, or national accounts, track flows of money among economic sectors.

  • Households receive factor income in the form of wages, profit from ownership of stocks, interest paid on bonds, and rent. They also receive government transfers.

  • Households allocate disposable income between consumer spending and private savings—funds that flow into the financial markets, financing investment spending and any government borrowing.

  • Government purchases of goods and services are total expenditures by federal, state, and local governments on goods and services.

  • Exports lead to a flow of funds into the country. Imports lead to a flow of funds out of the country.

  • Gross domestic product, or GDP, can be calculated in three different ways: add up the value added by all firms; add up all spending on domestically produced final goods and services, an amount equal to aggregate spending; or add up all factor income paid by firms. Intermediate goods and services are not included in the calculation of GDP, while changes in inventories and net exports are.

22-1

  1. Question 7.1

    Explain why the three methods of calculating GDP produce the same estimate of GDP.

  2. Question 7.2

    What are the various sectors to which firms make sales? What are the various ways in which households are linked with other sectors of the economy?

  3. Question 7.3

    Consider Figure 22-2 and suppose you mistakenly believed that total value added was $30,500, the sum of the sales price of a car and a car’s worth of steel. What items would you be counting twice?

Solutions appear at back of book.