A banking crisis occurs when a large part of the depository banking sector or the shadow banking sector fails or threatens to fail.
Bank failures are common: even in a good year, several U.S. banks typically go under for one reason or another. And shadow banks sometimes fail, too. Banking crises—episodes in which a large part of the depository banking sector or the shadow banking sector fails or threatens to fail—
When many banks—
In an asset bubble, the price of an asset is pushed to an unreasonably high level due to expectations of further price gains.
Shared Mistakes In practice, banking crises usually owe their origins to many banks making the same mistake of investing in an asset bubble. In an asset bubble, the price of some kind of asset, such as housing, is pushed to an unreasonably high level by investors’ expectations of further price gains. For a while, such bubbles can feed on themselves. A good example is the savings and loan crisis of the 1980s, when there was a huge boom in the construction of commercial real estate, especially office buildings. Many banks extended large loans to real estate developers, believing that the boom would continue indefinitely. By the late 1980s, it became clear that developers had gotten carried away, building far more office space than the country needed. Unable to rent out their space or forced to slash rents, a number of developers defaulted on their loans—
A similar phenomenon occurred between 2002 and 2006, when rapidly rising housing prices led many people to borrow heavily to buy a house in the belief that prices would keep rising. This process accelerated as more buyers rushed into the market and pushed housing prices up even faster. Eventually the market runs out of new buyers and the bubble bursts. At this point asset prices fall; in some parts of the United States, housing prices fell by half between 2006 and 2009. This, in turn, undermines confidence in financial institutions that are exposed to losses due to falling asset prices. This loss of confidence, if it’s sufficiently severe, can set in motion the kind of economy-
A financial contagion is a vicious downward spiral among depository banks or shadow banks: each bank’s failure worsens fears and increases the likelihood that another bank will fail.
Financial Contagion In especially severe banking crises, a vicious downward spiral of financial contagion occurs among depository banks or shadow banks: each institution’s failure worsens depositors’ or lenders’ fears and increases the odds that another bank will fail.
As already noted, one underlying cause of contagion arises from the logic of bank runs. In the case of depository banks, when one bank fails, depositors are likely to become nervous about others. Similarly in the case of shadow banks, when one fails, lenders in the short-
There is also a second channel of contagion: asset markets and the vicious cycle of deleveraging, a phenomenon we learned about in Chapter 29. When a financial institution is under pressure to reduce debt and raise cash, it tries to sell assets. To sell assets quickly, though, it often has to sell them at a deep discount. The contagion comes from the fact that other financial institutions own similar assets, whose prices decline as a result of the “fire sale.” This decline in asset prices hurts the other financial institutions’ financial positions, too, leading their creditors to stop lending to them. This knock-
A financial panic is a sudden and widespread disruption of the financial markets that occurs when people suddenly lose faith in the liquidity of financial institutions and markets.
Combine an asset bubble with a huge, unregulated shadow-
Because banking provides much of the liquidity needed for trading financial assets like stocks and bonds, severe banking crises almost always lead to disruptions of the stock and bond markets. Disruptions of these markets, along with a headlong rush to sell assets and raise cash, lead to a vicious circle of deleveraging. As the panic unfolds, savers and investors come to believe that the safest place for their money is under their bed, and their hoarding of cash further deepens the distress.
So what can history tell us about banking crises and financial panics?
Between the Civil War and the Great Depression, the United States had a famously crisis-
Table 32-1 shows the dates of these nationwide banking crises and the number of banks that failed in each episode. Notice that the table is divided into two parts. The first part is devoted to the “national banking era,” which preceded the 1913 creation of the Federal Reserve—
National Banking era (1863– |
Great Depression (1929– |
||
---|---|---|---|
Panic dates |
Number of failures |
Panic dates |
Number of failures |
September 1873 |
101 |
November– |
806 |
May 1884 |
42 |
April– |
573 |
November 1890 |
18 |
September– |
827 |
May– |
503 |
June– |
283 |
October– |
73* |
February– |
Bank holiday (government- |
*This understates the scale of the 1907 crisis because it doesn’t take into account the role of trusts. |
TABLE 17-
The events that sparked each of these panics differed. In the nineteenth century, there was a boom-
As we’ll see later in this chapter, the major financial panics of the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries were followed by severe economic downturns. However, the banking crises of the early 1930s made previous crises seem minor by comparison. In four successive waves of bank runs from 1930 to 1932, about 40% of the banks in America failed. In the end, Franklin Delano Roosevelt declared a temporary closure of all banks—
There is still considerable controversy about the banking crisis of the early 1930s. In part, this controversy is about cause and effect: did the banking crisis cause the wider economic crisis, or vice versa? (No doubt causation ran in both directions, but the magnitude of these effects remains disputed.) There is also controversy about the extent to which the banking crisis could have been avoided. Milton Friedman and Anna Schwartz, in their famous study A Monetary History of the United States, argued that the Federal Reserve could and should have prevented the banking crisis—
In the United States, the experience of the 1930s led to banking reforms that prevented a replay for more than 70 years. Outside the United States, however, there were a number of major banking crises.
Around the world, banking crises are relatively frequent events. However, the ways in which they occur differ according to the banking sector’s particular institutional framework. According to a 2008 analysis by the International Monetary Fund, no fewer than 127 banking crises occurred around the world between 1970 and 2007. Most of these were in small, poor countries that lack the regulatory safeguards found in advanced countries. In poorer countries, banks generally get in trouble in much the same way: insufficient capital, poor accounting, too many loans and, often, corruption. But banks in advanced countries can also make the same mistakes—
In more advanced countries, banking crises almost always occur as a consequence of an asset bubble—
In the United States, the fall of Lehman in September 2008 precipitated a banking crisis in the shadow banking sector that included financial contagion as well as financial panic, but left the depository banking sector largely unaffected. As we discussed in the opening story, the financial crisis of 2008 was devastating because of securitization, which had distributed subprime mortgage loans throughout the entire shadow banking sector both in the United States and abroad.
At the time of writing, shadow banking in the United States was still significantly smaller than it was before the crisis. Since 2008, investors have rediscovered the benefits of regulation, and the depository banking sector has grown at the expense of the shadow banking sector. However, shadow banking has certainly not gone away. China’s shadow banking sector has grown at breakneck speed in the last few years, making it the third largest in the world as of 2014 and an area of great concern to Chinese leaders. In the next section, we will learn how troubles in the banking sector soon translate into troubles for the broader economy.
Erin Go Broke
For much of the 1990s and 2000s, Ireland was celebrated as an economic success story: the “Celtic Tiger” was growing at a pace the rest of Europe could only envy. But the miracle came to an abrupt halt in 2008, as Ireland found itself facing a huge banking crisis.
Like the earlier banking crises in Finland, Sweden, and Japan, Ireland’s crisis grew out of excessive optimism about real estate. Irish housing prices began rising in the 1990s, in part a result of the economy’s strong growth. However, real estate developers began betting on ever-
In 2007 the Irish real estate boom collapsed. Home prices started falling, and home sales collapsed. Many of the loans that Irish banks had made during the boom went into default. Now, so-
This created a new problem because it put Irish taxpayers on the hook for potentially huge bank losses. Until the crisis struck, Ireland appeared to be in good fiscal shape, with relatively low government debt and a budget surplus. The fallout from the banking crisis, however, led to serious questions about the solvency of the Irish government—
As in most banking crises, Ireland experienced a severe recession. The Irish unemployment rate rose from less than 5% before the crisis to more than 15% in early 2012. It was still more than 11% at the time of writing.
It’s also worth noting that Ireland’s problems were part of a broader crisis affecting several European countries, notably Spain, Portugal, and Greece. We’ll discuss this broader crisis later in the chapter.
Although individual bank failures are common, a banking crisis is a rare event that typically will severely harm the broader economy.
A banking crisis can occur because depository or shadow banks invest in an asset bubble or through financial contagion, set off by bank runs or by a vicious cycle of deleveraging. Largely unregulated, shadow banking is particularly vulnerable to contagion.
In 2008, an asset bubble combined with a huge shadow banking sector and a vicious cycle of deleveraging created a financial panic and banking crisis, as savers cut their spending and investors hoarded their funds, sending the economy into a steep decline.
Between the Civil War and the Great Depression, the United States suffered numerous banking crises and financial panics, each followed by a severe economic downturn. The banking reforms of the 1930s prevented another banking crisis until 2008.
Banking crises usually occur in small, poor countries, although there have been banking crises in advanced countries as well. The fall of Lehman caused a banking crisis and a financial panic in the shadow banking sector, leading investors to shift back into the depository banking sector.
Regarding the Economics in Action “Erin Go Broke,” identify the following:
The asset bubble
The channel of financial contagion
Again regarding “Erin Go Broke,” why do you think the Irish government tried to stabilize the situation by guaranteeing the debts of the banks? Why was this a questionable policy?
Solutions appear at back of book.