The Ordinary Business of Life

Imagine that you could transport an American from the colonial period forward in time to our own era. (Isn’t that the plot of a movie? Several, actually.) What would this time-traveler find amazing?

Surely the most amazing thing would be the sheer prosperity of modern America—the range of goods and services that ordinary families can afford. Looking at all that wealth, our transplanted colonial would wonder, “How can I get some of that?” Or perhaps he would ask himself, “How can my society get some of that?”

An economy is a system for coordinating society’s productive activities.

Economics is the social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services.

The answer is that to get this kind of prosperity, you need a well-functioning system for coordinating productive activities—the activities that create the goods and services people want and get them to the people who want them. That kind of system is what we mean when we talk about the economy. And economics is the social science that studies the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services. As the great nineteenth-century economist Alfred Marshall put it, economics is “a study of mankind in the ordinary business of life.”

An economy succeeds to the extent that it, literally, delivers the goods. A time-traveler from the eighteenth century—or even from 1950—would be amazed at how many goods and services the modern American economy delivers and at how many people can afford them. Compared with any past economy and with all but a few other countries today, America has an incredibly high standard of living.

A market economy is an economy in which decisions about production and consumption are made by individual producers and consumers.

So our economy must be doing something right, and the time-traveler might want to compliment the person in charge. But guess what? There isn’t anyone in charge. The United States has a market economy, in which production and consumption are the result of decentralized decisions by many firms and individuals. There is no central authority telling people what to produce or where to ship it. Each individual producer makes what he or she thinks will be most profitable; each consumer buys what he or she chooses.

The alternative to a market economy is a command economy, in which there is a central authority making decisions about production and consumption. Command economies have been tried, most notably in the Soviet Union between 1917 and 1991. But they didn’t work very well. Producers in the Soviet Union routinely found themselves unable to produce because they did not have crucial raw materials, or they succeeded in producing but then found that nobody wanted their products. Consumers were often unable to find necessary items—command economies are famous for long lines at shops.

Market economies, however, are able to coordinate even highly complex activities and to reliably provide consumers with the goods and services they want. Indeed, people quite casually trust their lives to the market system: residents of any major city would starve in days if the unplanned yet somehow orderly actions of thousands of businesses did not deliver a steady supply of food. Surprisingly, the unplanned “chaos” of a market economy turns out to be far more orderly than the “planning” of a command economy.

The invisible hand refers to the way in which the individual pursuit of self-interest can lead to good results for society as a whole.

In 1776, in a famous passage in his book The Wealth of Nations, the pioneering Scottish economist Adam Smith wrote about how individuals, in pursuing their own interests, often end up serving the interests of society as a whole. Of a businessman whose pursuit of profit makes the nation wealthier, Smith wrote: “[H]e intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention.” Ever since, economists have used the term invisible hand to refer to the way a market economy manages to harness the power of self-interest for the good of society.

3

Microeconomics is the branch of economics that studies how people make decisions and how these decisions interact.

The study of how individuals make decisions and how these decisions interact is called microeconomics. One of the key themes in microeconomics is the validity of Adam Smith’s insight: individuals pursuing their own interests often do promote the interests of society as a whole.

So part of the answer to our time-traveler’s question—“How can my society achieve the kind of prosperity you take for granted?”—is that his society should learn to appreciate the virtues of a market economy and the power of the invisible hand.

But the invisible hand isn’t always our friend. It’s also important to understand when and why the individual pursuit of self-interest can lead to counterproductive behavior.

© Ted Rall. Reprinted with permission of Universal Press Syndicate. All rights reserved.

My Benefit, Your Cost

One thing that our time-traveler would not admire about modern life is the traffic. In fact, although most things have gotten better in America over time, traffic congestion has gotten a lot worse.

When traffic is congested, each driver is imposing a cost on all the other drivers on the road—he is literally getting in their way (and they are getting in his way). This cost can be substantial: in major metropolitan areas, each time someone drives to work, instead of taking public transportation or working at home, he can easily impose $15 or more in hidden costs on other drivers. Yet when deciding whether or not to drive, commuters have no incentive to take the costs they impose on others into account.

When the individual pursuit of self-interest leads to bad results for society as a whole, there is market failure.

Traffic congestion is a familiar example of a much broader problem: sometimes the individual pursuit of one’s own interest, instead of promoting the interests of society as a whole, can actually make society worse off. When this happens, it is known as market failure. Other important examples of market failure involve air and water pollution as well as the overexploitation of natural resources such as fish and forests.

The good news, as you will learn as you use this book to study microeconomics, is that economic analysis can be used to diagnose cases of market failure. And often, economic analysis can also be used to devise solutions for the problem.

Good Times, Bad Times

Normally our time-traveler would find shopping malls crowded with happy customers. But during the fall of 2008, stores across America became unusually quiet. The U.S. economy was depressed, and businesses were laying off workers in large numbers.

A recession is a downturn in the economy.

Such troubled periods are a regular feature of modern economies. The fact is that the economy does not always run smoothly: it experiences fluctuations, a series of ups and downs. By middle age, a typical American will have experienced three or four downs, known as recessions. (The U.S. economy experienced serious recessions beginning in 1973, 1981, 1990, 2001, and 2007.) During a severe recession, millions of workers may be laid off.

4

Macroeconomics is the branch of economics that is concerned with overall ups and downs in the economy.

Like market failure, recessions are a fact of life; but also like market failure, they are a problem for which economic analysis offers some solutions. Recessions are one of the main concerns of the branch of economics known as macroeconomics, which is concerned with the overall ups and downs of the economy. If you study macroeconomics, you will learn how economists explain recessions and how government policies can be used to minimize the damage from economic fluctuations.

Despite the occasional recession, however, over the long run the story of the U.S. economy contains many more ups than downs.

Onward and Upward

At the beginning of the twentieth century, most Americans lived under conditions that we would now think of as extreme poverty. Only 10% of homes had flush toilets, only 8% had central heating, only 2% had electricity, and almost nobody had a car, let alone a washing machine or air conditioning.

Economic growth is the growing ability of the economy to produce goods and services.

Such comparisons are a stark reminder of how much our lives have been changed by economic growth, the growing ability of the economy to produce goods and services. Why does the economy grow over time? And why does economic growth occur faster in some times and places than in others? These are key questions for economics because economic growth is a good thing, and most of us want more of it.

The “ordinary business of life” is really quite extraordinary, if you stop to think about it, and it can lead us to ask some very interesting and important questions.

In this book, we will describe the answers economists have given to these questions. But this book, like economics as a whole, isn’t a list of answers: it’s an introduction to a discipline, a way to address questions like those we have just asked. Or as Alfred Marshall put it: “Economics … is not a body of concrete truth, but an engine for the discovery of concrete truth.”

So let’s turn the key and start the ignition.

Quick Review

  • Economics is the study of the production, distribution, and consumption of goods and services and how the economy coordinates these activities. In a market economy, the invisible hand works through individuals pursuing their own self-interest.
  • Microeconomics is the study of how individuals make decisions and how these decisions interact, which sometimes leads to market failure. Macroeconomics is concerned with economic fluctuations, such as recessions, that can temporarily slow economic growth.

Check Your Understanding 1-1

  1. Which of the following statements describe features of a market economy?
    1. Question

      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
      This illustrates the concept of opportunity cost. Given that a person can only eat so much at one sitting, having a slice of chocolate cake requires that you forgo eating something else, such as a slice of coconut cream pie.
    2. Question

      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
      This illustrates the concept that resources are scarce. Even if there were more resources in the world, the total amount of those resources would be limited. As a result, scarcity would still arise. For there to be no scarcity, there would have to be unlimited amounts of everything (including unlimited time in a human life), which is clearly impossible.
    3. Question

      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
      This illustrates the concept that people usually exploit opportunities to make themselves better off. Students will seek to make themselves better off by signing up for the tutorials of teaching assistants with good reputations and avoiding those teaching assistants with poor reputations. It also illustrates the concept that resources are scarce. If there were unlimited spaces in tutorials with good teaching assistants, they would not fill up.

Solutions appear at back of book.