External Costs and Benefits

An external cost is an uncompensated cost that an individual or firm imposes on others.

The environmental costs of pollution are the best known and most important example of an external cost—an uncompensated cost that an individual or firm imposes on others. In a modern economy there are many examples of an external cost that an individual or firm imposes on others. A very familiar one is the external cost of traffic congestion: an individual who chooses to drive during rush hour increases congestion and has no incentive to take into account the inconvenience inflicted on other drivers. Another familiar example is the cost created by people who text while driving, increasing the risk of accidents that will harm others as well as themselves (see the upcoming For Inquiring Minds).

Pollution leads to an external cost because in the absence of government intervention those who decide how much pollution to create have no incentive to take into account the costs of pollution that they impose on others. In the case of air pollution from a coal-fired power plant, the power company has no incentive to take into account the health costs imposed upon people who breathe dirty air. Instead, the company’s incentives are determined by the private monetary costs and benefits of generating power, such as the price of coal, the price earned for a kilowatt of energy, and so on.

An external benefit is a benefit that an individual or firm confers on others without receiving compensation.

External costs and benefits are known as externalities. External costs are negative externalities, and external benefits are positive externalities.

We’ll see later in this chapter that there are also important examples of external benefits, benefits that individuals or firms confer on others without receiving compensation. For example, when you get a flu shot, you are less likely to pass on the flu virus to your roommates. Yet you alone incur the monetary cost of the vaccination and the painful jab. Businesses that develop new technologies also generate external benefits, because their ideas often contribute to innovation by other firms.

External costs and benefits are jointly known as externalities, with external costs called negative externalities and external benefits called positive externalities. Externalities can lead to private decisions—that is, decisions by individuals or firms—that are not optimal for society as a whole. Let’s take a closer look at why.

!worldview! FOR INQUIRING MINDS: Talking, Texting, and Driving

Why is that person in the car in front of us driving so erratically? Is the driver drunk? No, the driver is talking on the phone or texting.

Traffic safety experts take the risks posed by driving while using a cell phone very seriously: A recent study found a six-fold increase in accidents caused by this type of driving while distracted. And in 2012, the National Safety Council estimated that nearly 250,000, or one in four traffic accidents, was attributed to the use of cell phones while driving.

One estimate suggests that talking while driving may be responsible for 3,000 or more traffic deaths each year. And using hands-free, voice-activated devices to make a call doesn’t seem to help much because the main danger is distraction. As one traffic consultant put it, “It’s not where your eyes are; it’s where your head is.”

Using a cell phone while driving makes you a danger to others as well as yourself.
Steve Debenport/Getty Images

The National Safety Council urges people not to use cell-phones while driving. Most states have some restrictions on cell-phone use while driving. But in response to a growing number of accidents, several states have banned cell-phone use behind the wheel altogether. In 43 states and the District of Columbia, it is illegal to text and drive. Cell-phone use while driving is illegal in many other countries as well, including Japan and Israel.

Why not leave the decision up to the driver? Because the risk posed by driving while using a cell phone isn’t just a risk to the driver; it’s also a safety risk to others—to a driver’s passengers, pedestrians, and people in other cars. Even if you decide that the benefit to you of using your cell phone while driving is worth the cost, you aren’t taking into account the cost to other people. Driving while using a cell phone, in other words, generates a serious—and sometimes fatal—negative externality.

Pollution: An External Cost

Pollution is a bad thing. Yet most pollution is a side effect of activities that provide us with good things: our air is polluted by power plants generating the electricity that lights our cities, and our rivers are damaged by fertilizer runoff from farms that grow our food. And groundwater contamination may occur from fracking, which also produces cleaner-burning fuel. Why shouldn’t we accept a certain amount of pollution as the cost of a good life?

Actually, we do. Even highly committed environmentalists don’t think that we can or should completely eliminate pollution—even an environmentally conscious society would accept some pollution as the cost of producing useful goods and services. What environmentalists argue is that unless there is a strong and effective environmental policy, our society will generate too much pollution—too much of a bad thing. And the great majority of economists agree.

To see why, we need a framework that lets us think about how much pollution a society should have. We’ll then be able to see why a market economy, left to itself, will produce more pollution than it should. We’ll start by adopting the simplest framework to study the problem—assuming that the amount of pollution emitted by a polluter is directly observable and controllable.

The Socially Optimal Quantity of Pollution

How much pollution should society allow? We learned in Chapter 9 that “how much” decisions always involve comparing the marginal benefit from an additional unit of something with the marginal cost of that additional unit. The same is true of pollution.

The marginal social cost of pollution is the additional cost imposed on society as a whole by an additional unit of pollution.

The marginal social cost of pollution is the additional cost imposed on society as a whole by an additional unit of pollution.

For example, sulfur dioxide from coal-fired power plants mixes with rainwater to form acid rain, which damages fisheries, crops, and forests, while groundwater contamination, which may be a side effect of fracking, damages health. Typically, the marginal social cost of pollution is increasing—each additional unit of pollution emitted causes a greater level of damage than the unit before. That’s because nature can often safely handle low levels of pollution but is increasingly harmed as pollution reaches higher levels.

The marginal social benefit of pollution is the additional gain to society as a whole from an additional unit of pollution.

The marginal social benefit of pollution is the benefit to society from an additional unit of pollution. This may seem like a confusing concept—how can there be any benefit to society from pollution? The answer lies in the understanding that pollution can be reduced—but at a cost. For example, air pollution from coal-fired power plants can be reduced by using more-expensive coal and expensive scrubbing technology; contamination of drinking water due to fracking can be limited with more-expensive drilling techniques; wastewater contamination of rivers and oceans can be reduced by building water treatment facilities.

All these methods of reducing pollution have an opportunity cost. That is, avoiding pollution requires using scarce resources that could have been employed to produce other goods and services. So the marginal social benefit of pollution is the goods and services that could be had by society if it tolerated another unit of pollution.

Comparisons between the pollution levels tolerated in rich and poor countries illustrate the importance of the level of the marginal social benefit of pollution in deciding how much pollution a society wishes to tolerate. Because poor countries have a higher opportunity cost of resources spent on reducing pollution than richer countries, they tolerate higher levels of pollution. For example, the World Health Organization has estimated that 3.5 million people in poor countries die prematurely from breathing polluted indoor air caused by burning dirty fuels like wood, dung, and coal to heat and cook—a situation that residents of rich countries can afford to avoid.

The socially optimal quantity of pollution is the quantity of pollution that society would choose if all the costs and benefits of pollution were fully accounted for.

Using hypothetical numbers, Figure 16-1 shows how we can determine the socially optimal quantity of pollution—the quantity of pollution society would choose if all the social costs and benefits were fully accounted for. The upward-sloping marginal social cost curve, MSC, shows how the marginal cost to society of an additional unit of pollution varies with the quantity of pollution. As we mentioned, marginal social cost of pollution is typically increasing, as another unit of pollution causes more harm than prior units. The marginal social benefit curve, MSB, is downward sloping. At high levels of pollution, the cost of achieving a reduction in pollution is fairly small. However, as pollution levels drop, it becomes progressively more costly to engineer a further fall in pollution as more expensive techniques must be used, so the MSB is higher at lower levels of pollution..

The Socially Optimal Quantity of Pollution Pollution yields both costs and benefits. Here the curve MSC shows how the marginal cost to society as a whole from emitting one more unit of pollution emissions depends on the quantity of emissions. The MSC curve is upward sloping, so the marginal social cost increases as pollution increases. The curve MSB shows how the marginal benefit to society as a whole of emitting an additional unit of pollution emissions depends on the quantity of pollution emissions. The MSB curve is downward sloping, so the marginal social benefit falls as pollution increases. The socially optimal quantity of pollution is QOPT; at that quantity, the marginal social benefit of pollution is equal to the marginal social cost, corresponding to $200.

The socially optimal quantity of pollution in this example isn’t zero. It’s QOPT, the quantity corresponding to point O, where MSB crosses MSC. At QOPT, the marginal social benefit from an additional unit of pollution and its marginal social cost are equalized at $200.

But will a market economy, left to itself, arrive at the socially optimal quantity of pollution? No, it won’t.

Why a Market Economy Produces Too Much Pollution

While pollution yields both benefits and costs to society, in a market economy without government intervention too much pollution will be produced. In that case it is polluters alone—owners of power plants or gas-drilling companies, for example—who decide how much pollution is created. And they have no incentive to take into account the cost that pollution inflicts on others.

Figure 16-2 shows the result of this asymmetry between who reaps the benefits and who pays the costs. In a market economy without government intervention, since polluters are the only ones making the decisions, only the benefits of pollution are taken into account when choosing how much pollution to produce. So instead of producing the socially optimal quantity, QOPT, the market economy will generate the amount QMKT. At QMKT, the marginal social benefit of an additional unit of pollution is zero, while the marginal social cost of an additional unit is much higher—$400.

Why a Market Economy Produces Too Much Pollution In the absence of government intervention, the quantity of pollution will be QMKT, the level at which the marginal social benefit of pollution is zero. This is an inefficiently high quantity of pollution: the marginal social cost, $400, greatly exceeds the marginal social benefit, $0. An optimal Pigouvian tax* of $200, the value of the marginal social cost of pollution when it equals the marginal social benefit of pollution, can move the market to the socially optimal quantity of pollution, QOPT.
Pigouvian taxes will be covered in the next section on pollution policy.

Why? Well, take a moment to consider what the polluter would do if he found himself emitting QOPT of pollution. Remember that the MSB curve represents the resources made available by tolerating one more unit of pollution. The polluter would notice that if he increases his emission of pollution by moving down the MSB curve from QOPT to QH, he would gain $200 − $100 = $100. That gain of $100 comes from using less-expensive but higher-emission production techniques. Remember, he suffers none of the costs of doing this—only others do. However, it won’t stop there. At QH, he notices that if he increases his emissions from QH to QMKT, he would gain another $100 as he moves down the MSB curve yet again. This would be achieved by using even cheaper and higher-emission production techniques. He will stop at QMKT because at this emission level the marginal social benefit of a unit of pollution is zero. That is, at QMKT he gains nothing by using yet cheaper and dirtier production techniques and emitting more pollution.

The market outcome, QMKT, is inefficient. Recall that an outcome is inefficient if someone could be made better off without someone else being made worse off. At an inefficient outcome, a mutually beneficial trade is being missed. At QMKT, the benefit accruing to the polluter of the last unit of pollution is very low—virtually zero. But the cost imposed on society of that last unit of pollution is quite high—$400. So by reducing the quantity of pollution at QMKT by one unit, the total social cost of pollution falls by $400 but the total social benefit falls by virtually zero.

So total surplus rises by approximately $400 if the quantity of pollution at QMKT is reduced by one unit. At QMKT, society would be willing to pay the polluter up to $400 not to emit the last unit of pollution, and the polluter would be willing to accept their offer since that last unit gains him virtually nothing. But because there is no means in this market economy for this transaction to take place, an inefficient outcome occurs.

Private Solutions to Externalities

As we’ve just seen, externalities in a market economy cause inefficiency: there is a mutually beneficial trade that is being missed. So can the private sector solve the problem of externalities without government intervention? Will individuals be able to make that deal on their own?

According to the Coase theorem, even in the presence of externalities an economy can always reach an efficient solution as long as transaction costs—the costs to individuals of making a deal—are sufficiently low.

In an influential 1960 article, the economist and Nobel laureate Ronald Coase pointed out that in an ideal world the private sector could indeed solve the problem of inefficiency caused by externalities. According to the Coase theorem, even in the presence of externalities an economy can always reach an efficient solution provided that the costs of making a deal are sufficiently low. The costs of making a deal are known as transaction costs.

For an illustration of how the Coase theorem might work, consider the case of groundwater contamination caused by drilling. There are two ways a private transaction can address this problem. First, landowners whose groundwater is at risk of contamination can pay drillers to use more-expensive, less-polluting technology. Second, the drilling companies can pay landowners the value of damage to their groundwater sources—say, by buying their properties outright so that the landowners move. If drillers legally have the right to pollute, then the first outcome is more likely. If drillers don’t legally have the right to pollute, then the second is more likely.

When individuals take external costs or benefits into account, they internalize the externality.

What Coase argued is that, either way, if transaction costs are sufficiently low, then drillers and landowners can make a mutually beneficial deal. Regardless of how the transaction is structured, the social cost of the pollution is taken into account in decision making. When individuals take externalities into account when making decisions, economists say that they internalize the externality. In that case the outcome is efficient without government intervention.

So why don’t private parties always internalize externalities? The problem is transaction costs in one form or another that prevent an efficient outcome. Here is a sample:

To be sure, there are examples in the real world in which private parties internalize the externalities. Take the case of private communities that set rules for appearances—no cars on blocks in the driveway!—and behavior—no loud parties at midnight! These rules internalize the externality that one homeowner’s lack of upkeep or rowdy behavior has on the market value of a neighbor’s house. But for major externalities like widespread pollution, it is necessary to look for government solutions because transaction costs are just too high to achieve an efficient private outcome.

In some cases, people do find ways to reduce transaction costs, allowing them to internalize externalities. For example, a house with a junk-filled yard and peeling paint imposes a negative externality on the neighboring houses, diminishing their value in the eyes of potential home buyers. So, many people live in private communities that set rules for home maintenance and behavior, making bargaining between neighbors unnecessary. But in many other cases, transaction costs are too high to make it possible to deal with externalities through private action. For example, tens of millions of people are adversely affected by acid rain. It would be prohibitively expensive to try to make a deal among all those people and all those power companies.

When transaction costs prevent the private sector from dealing with externalities, it is time to look for government solutions. We turn to public policy in the next section.

ECONOMICS in Action: How Much Does Your Electricity Really Cost?

How Much Does Your Electricity Really Cost?

In 2011, three leading economists, Nicholas Z. Muller, Robert Mendelsohn, and William Nordhaus, published a paper drawn from the results of an ambitious study that estimated the external cost of pollution generated by 10,000 pollution sources in the United States, broken down by industry. In it they model the costs to society of emissions of six major pollutants: sulfur dioxide, nitrogen oxides, volatile organic compounds, ammonia, fine particulate matter, and coarse particulate matter. The costs took a variety of forms, from harmful effects on health to reduced agricultural yields. In the case of the electricity-generating sector, the authors also included the cost to society from carbon dioxide emissions—one of many greenhouse gases, the pollution that causes climate change. For each industry a total external cost of pollution, or TEC, was calculated and then compared to the total value to society, or TVC, created by that industry.

What is the social cost of carbon?
Denis Pepin/Shutterstock

An industry with a TEC/TVC ratio greater than 1 indicates that the external cost of pollution exceeds the value created. In other words, a ratio greater than 1 means that a marginal reduction in both industry output and its ensuing pollution increases total social welfare. But as the authors of the study emphasize, this doesn’t mean that the industry should be shut down. Rather, it means that the current level of pollution emitted is too high. A contentious issue in any model of the external cost of greenhouse gases—commonly known as SCC, the social cost of carbon—is exactly what price to assign to it. That’s because the negative effects of climate change fall most heavily on future generations.

So how do you value today the cost imposed on those not yet born? A difficult question, for sure. Economists address this puzzle by using a range of estimates for SCC. For example, in November 2013, the Environmental Protection Agency, or EPA, the federal agency tasked with protecting the environment, published estimates ranging from $12 to $116 and settled on a cost of $37 per metric ton of carbon dioxide.

Using a relatively conservative estimate of $27 for SCC, Muller, Mendelsohn, and Nordhaus compare the TEC/TVC ratio and the TEC per kilowatt-hour produced for two types of electricity generation—coal-fired plants and natural gas-fired plants.

TEC/TVC

TEC/kilowatt-hour

Coal

2.83

$0.039

Natural gas

1.30

0.005

As you can see, both modes of electricity generation are under-regulated: with TEC/TVC ratios greater than 1, society would benefit from a reduction in their emissions. And although both emit greenhouse gases, the TEC per kilowatt-hour generated with natural gas is nearly one-eighth the cost of one generated with coal. That’s because natural gas burns cleaner than coal and produces less-toxic pollutants. With the average kilowatt-hour in the United States costing a little over $0.11 in 2013, a conservative estimate of the external cost of that kilowatt hour is one-third of the retail price when generated by coal, and one-twentieth when generated by natural gas.

In response to growing concerns about carbon emissions, in early 2014 the EPA issued rules that limited the amount of carbon emitted by newly constructed coal-fired and natural gas-fired plants. The rules are unlikely to hinder the construction of new natural gas-fired plants because the latest technology meets the standard. Under the new rules, however, new coal-fired plants cannot be built unless they use carbon-capture and storage technology, which captures 20% to 40% of their carbon emissions and stores them underground. While coal advocates argue that the new rules will effectively stop construction of new coal-fired plants, market forces have increasingly tilted toward natural gas over coal as the use of fracking has made the cost of natural gas plummet.

Quick Review

  • External costs and benefits are known as externalities. Pollution is an example of an external cost, or negative externality; in contrast, some activities can give rise to external benefits, or positive externalities.

  • There are costs as well as benefits to reducing pollution, so the optimal quantity of pollution isn’t zero. Instead, the socially optimal quantity of pollution is the quantity at which the marginal social cost of pollution is equal to the marginal social benefit of pollution.

  • Left to itself, a market economy will typically generate an inefficiently high level of pollution because polluters have no incentive to take into account the costs they impose on others.

  • According to the Coase theorem, the private sector can sometimes resolve externalities on its own: if transaction costs aren’t too high, individuals can reach a deal to internalize the externality. When transaction costs are too high, government intervention may be warranted.

16-1

  1. Question 16.1

    Wastewater runoff from large poultry farms adversely affects their neighbors. Explain the following:

    1. The nature of the external cost imposed

    2. The outcome in the absence of government intervention or a private deal

    3. The socially optimal outcome

  2. Question 16.2

    According to Yasmin, any student who borrows a book from the university library and fails to return it on time imposes a negative externality on other students. She claims that rather than charging a modest fine for late returns, the library should charge a huge fine so that borrowers will never return a book late. Is Yasmin’s economic reasoning correct?

Solutions appear at back of book.