1.1 Module 60: The Multiplier

Thinkstock

WHAT YOU WILL LEARN

  • The significance of the marginal propensity to consume
  • The nature of the multiplier, which shows how initial changes in spending lead to further changes in spending

The Multiplier: An Informal Introduction

The story of the boom and bust in Ft. Myers that opens this section involves a sort of chain reaction in which an initial rise or fall in aggregate spending leads to changes in income, which lead to further changes in aggregate spending, and so on. Let’s examine that chain reaction more closely, this time thinking through the effects of changes in aggregate spending in the economy as a whole.

For the sake of this analysis, we’ll make four simplifying assumptions that we’ll revisit later.

  1. We assume that producers are willing to supply additional output at a fixed price. That is, if consumers or businesses buying investment goods decide to spend an additional $1 billion, that will translate into the production of $1 billion worth of additional goods and services without driving up the overall level of prices. As a result, changes in aggregate spending translate into changes in aggregate output, as measured by real GDP. As we’ll learn, this assumption isn’t too unrealistic in the short run, but it needs to be changed when we think about the long-run effects of changes in demand.
  2. We take the interest rate as given.
  3. We assume that there is no government spending and no taxes.
  4. We assume that exports and imports are zero.

Given these simplifying assumptions, consider what happens if there is a change in investment spending. Specifically, imagine that for some reason home builders decide to spend an extra $100 billion on home construction over the next year.

The direct effect of this increase in investment spending will be to increase income and the value of aggregate output by the same amount. That’s because each dollar spent on home construction translates into a dollar’s worth of income for construction workers, suppliers of building materials, electricians, and so on. If the process stopped there, the increase in housing investment spending would raise overall income by exactly $100 billion.

But the process doesn’t stop there. The increase in aggregate output leads to an increase in disposable income that flows to households in the form of profits and wages. The increase in households’ disposable income leads to a rise in consumer spending, which, in turn, induces firms to increase output yet again. This generates another rise in disposable income, which leads to another round of consumer spending increases, and so on. So there are multiple rounds of increases in aggregate output.

How large is the total effect on aggregate output if we sum the effect from all these rounds of spending increases? To answer this question, we need to introduce the concept of the marginal propensity to consume, or MPC: the increase in consumer spending when disposable income rises by $1. When consumer spending changes because of a rise or fall in disposable income, MPC is the change in consumer spending divided by the change in disposable income:

The marginal propensity to consume, or MPC, is the increase in consumer spending when disposable income rises by $1.

where the symbol Δ(delta) means “change in.” For example, if consumer spending goes up by $6 billion when disposable income goes up by $10 billion, MPC is $6 billion/$10 billion = 0.6.

The marginal propensity to save, or MPS, is the increase in household savings when disposable income rises by $1.

Because consumers normally spend part but not all of an additional dollar of disposable income, MPC is a number between 0 and 1. The additional disposable income that consumers don’t spend is saved; the marginal propensity to save, or MPS, is the fraction of an additional dollar of disposable income that is saved. MPS is equal to 1 − MPC.

Because we assumed that there are no taxes and no international trade, each $1 increase in aggregate spending raises both real GDP and disposable income by $1. So the $100 billion increase in investment spending initially raises real GDP by $100 billion. This leads to a second-round increase in consumer spending, which raises real GDP by a further MPC × $100 billion. It is followed by a third-round increase in consumer spending of MPC × MPC × $100 billion, and so on. After an infinite number of rounds, the total effect on real GDP is:

So the $100 billion increase in investment spending sets off a chain reaction in the economy. The net result of this chain reaction is that a $100 billion increase in investment spending leads to a change in real GDP that is a multiple of the size of that initial change in spending.

How large is this multiple? It’s a mathematical fact that an infinite series of the form 1 + x + x2 + x3 +…, where x is between 0 and 1, is equal to 1/(1 − x). So the total effect of a $100 billion increase in investment spending, I, taking into account all the subsequent increases in consumer spending (and assuming no taxes and no international trade), is given by:

Let’s consider a numerical example in which MPC = 0.6: each $1 in additional disposable income causes a $0.60 rise in consumer spending. In that case, a $100 billion increase in investment spending raises real GDP by $100 billion in the first round. The second-round increase in consumer spending raises real GDP by another 0.6 × $100 billion, or $60 billion. The third-round increase in consumer spending raises real GDP by another 0.6 × $60 billion, or $36 billion.

Table 60-1 shows the successive stages of increases, where “…” means the process goes on an infinite number of times. In the end, real GDP rises by $250 billion as a consequence of the initial $100 billion rise in investment spending:

Notice that even though there are an infinite number of rounds of expansion of real GDP, the total rise in real GDP is limited to $250 billion. The reason is that at each stage some of the rise in disposable income “leaks out” because it is saved. How much of an additional dollar of disposable income is saved depends on MPS, the marginal propensity to save.

We’ve described the effects of a change in investment spending, but the same analysis can be applied to any other change in aggregate spending. The important thing is to distinguish between the initial change in aggregate spending, before real GDP rises, and the additional change in aggregate spending caused by the change in real GDP as the chain reaction unfolds.

For example, suppose that a boom in housing prices makes consumers feel richer and that, as a result, they become willing to spend more at any given level of disposable income. This will lead to an initial rise in consumer spending, before real GDP rises. But it will also lead to second and later rounds of higher consumer spending as real GDP rises.

An autonomous change in aggregate spending is an initial change in the desired level of spending by firms, households, or government at a given level of real GDP.

The multiplier is the ratio of the total change in real GDP caused by an autonomous change in aggregate spending to the size of that autonomous change.

An initial rise or fall in aggregate spending at a given level of real GDP is called an autonomous change in aggregate spending. It’s autonomous—which means “self-governing”—because it’s the cause, not the result, of the chain reaction we’ve just described.

Formally, the multiplier is the ratio of the total change in real GDP caused by an autonomous change in aggregate spending to the size of that autonomous change. If we let ΔAAS stand for autonomous change in aggregate spending and ΔY stand for the change in real GDP, then the multiplier is equal to ΔYAAS. And we’ve already seen how to find the value of the multiplier. Assuming no taxes and no trade, the change in real GDP caused by an autonomous change in spending is:

Spending by one person or firm has a domino effect that leads to progressively more spending in the economy.
Thinkstock

So the multiplier is:

Notice that the size of the multiplier depends on MPC. If the marginal propensity to consume is high, so is the multiplier. This is true because the size of MPC determines how large each round of expansion is compared with the previous round. To put it another way, the higher MPC is, the less disposable income “leaks out” into savings at each round of expansion.

In later modules we’ll use the concept of the multiplier to analyze the effects of fiscal and monetary policies. We’ll also see that the formula for the multiplier changes when we introduce various complications, including taxes and foreign trade. First we need to look more deeply at what determines consumer spending.

THE MULTIPLIER AND THE GREAT DEPRESSION

The concept of the multiplier was originally devised by economists trying to understand the greatest economic disaster in history, the collapse of output and employment from 1929 to 1933, which began the Great Depression. Most economists believe that the slump from 1929 to 1933 was driven by a collapse in investment spending. But as the economy shrank, consumer spending also fell sharply, multiplying the effect on real GDP.

Table 60-2 shows what happened to investment spending, consumer spending, and GDP during those four terrible years. What we see is that investment spending imploded, falling by more than 80%. But consumer spending also fell drastically and actually accounted for more of the fall in real GDP. (The total fall in real GDP was larger than the combined fall in consumer and investment spending, mainly because of technical accounting issues.)

The numbers in Table 60-2 suggest that at the time of the Great Depression, the multiplier was around 3. Most current estimates put the size of the multiplier considerably lower—but there’s a reason for that change. In 1929, government in the United States was very small by modern standards: taxes were low and major government programs like Social Security and Medicare had not yet come into being. In the modern U.S. economy, taxes are much higher, and so is government spending. Why does this matter? Because taxes and some government programs act as automatic stabilizers, reducing the size of the multiplier.

Module 60 Review

Solutions appear at the back of the book.

Check Your Understanding

  1. Explain why a decline in investment spending caused by a change in business expectations leads to a fall in consumer spending.

  2. What is the multiplier if the marginal propensity to consume is 0.5? What is it if MPC is 0.8?

  3. As a percentage of GDP, savings accounts for a larger share of the economy in the country of Scania compared to the country of Amerigo. Which country is likely to have the larger multiplier? Explain.

Multiple-Choice Questions

  1. Question

    SrtufX1DIQLRgbheOMo6er3ZcXySvMu2VXnHKk0UH+Ojiazpz0lR72jm4ZTOCxHWizvnofvkbmvE7jqBF3oxPAzq/O5mlTdsacKo8jwvVvLiigk12mg7PDJz4W+aPehUYWV+mDAbrpGW1v1Dakewks8hlrKYEnFTFg9NDC+AoDYLn5sBWMAEhvqo5MdhQORS5tMCXU4GMEPc1kp/mn6Yvr9j8RZ6Vi6AUJZSAo5aroozh/f2EhMyQ8tQ0dzSR97NkDZajDOjI3INSebd+3gglv5v3sKKC9KSBZ5F84rUQdOzpvXdQDytbcHkeE3+Tm8KjpZn95f651sumymfYo+j5tVazifFVAS0ScxH7ERpP6YSU+6Z
  2. Question

    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
  3. Question

    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
  4. Question

    BrL0CEXcc7QpXglAJKxuziUR0BjFGByAvWPO1vtuhmCCp4nNNFzNMNrtObf+WXB3EsBr2bm+3/ykB6bR/+GpRZnWwbdfgiW4zwx9tRSvJlNyDg2Ffx/vqr4qOEkMADfmI2cuaigeahfff5g71YQm4HdbFVBf4VHbDkolWHq/ITshNcFzRoF+D58yhdFaCj+IQQuBOI/0nW/BKThbhmoZhYx+75UR/KAxiqOlcO5yZno3EqefBjnwcuLeX2HxQldugwrAkXChsA9KpqVMVpUCurXgieqDQLdJqqB34P4ks7K+T6r3kB6H21Evg8Q1TRql
  5. Question

    miiZSZRU/cdJPCCurxwtc4FZ+QBQCV2+mFRwjxgpK8O756oe8BVGGF/2AjxFaOqQHjErzpVC+lQVNjHVoGh5TgP3LAv2iLlCaM2XTEQ2w51pjI9qVxxzOLNqLL0nqWTsJ+CdwXhAawlgNibhM/S7jRmVPpGOniFRheNSM5xDLwkecWwaHNIua8RSafgx4Xe5EYCtwXIxBHnlgauE89Upd7wb6Q0Jk+dvuJVBKl/KCVDotXJ0JB+efTx5Fllff68NgExNB2nuG5+r9UwqHxt+QiITibrF2aGFtDDzWUqhGcx7C2ndP9Qt76zaT51cT9wz/ap6d6GirULmwo4vOb124iAZDt6y14ejRDDhsYbC92KvJSqP98zCWjH14gF9a4Rw7cmWLc6gKbvN5v6D

Critical-Thinking Questions

Explain how an autonomous change in aggregate spending affects real GDP, making reference to the multiplier concept.