Though cable cut into broadcast TV’s viewership, both types of programming came under scrutiny from the U.S. government. Initially, thanks to extensive lobbying efforts, cable’s growth was suppressed to ensure that no harm came to local broadcasters and traditional TV networks’ ad revenue streams. Later, as cable developed, FCC officials worried that power and profits were growing increasingly concentrated in fewer and fewer industry players’ hands. Thus the FCC set out to mitigate the situation through a variety of rules and regulations.
Government Regulations Temporarily Restrict Network Control
By the late 1960s, a progressive and active FCC, increasingly concerned about the monopoly-
In a second move, in 1970 the FCC created the Financial Interest and Syndication Rules—
The Department of Justice instituted a third policy action in 1975. Reacting to a number of legal claims against monopolistic practices, the Justice Department limited the networks’ production of non-
With the growth of cable and home video in the 1990s, the FCC gradually phased out the ban limiting network production because the TV market grew more competitive. Beginning in 1995, the networks were again allowed to syndicate and profit from rerun programs, but only from those they produced. The elimination of fin-
Balancing Cable’s Growth against Broadcasters’ Interests
By the early 1970s, cable’s rapid growth, capacity for more channels, and better reception led the FCC to seriously examine industry issues. In 1972, the commission updated or enacted two regulations with long-
Must-
First established by the FCC in 1965 and reaffirmed in 1972, the must-
Access-
In 1972, the FCC also mandated access channels in the nation’s top one hundred TV markets, requiring cable systems to provide and fund a tier of nonbroadcast channels dedicated to local education, government, and the public. The FCC required large-
ELSEWHERE IN MEDIA & CULTURE | |
IS THE ERA OF A MASS AUDIENCE OVER? p. 187 | |
12M the record breaking first print run of the last Harry Potter book p. 349 | $35.9B total global movie box office revenue in 2013 p. 255 |
CAN MOVIES CAUSE REAL- |
|
38% THE AMOUNT OF HOUSEHOLDS WITH A NETFLIX SUBSCRIPTION IN 2013 p. 261 |
Cable’s Role: Electronic Publisher or Common Carrier?
Because the Communications Act of 1934 had not anticipated cable, the industry’s regulatory status was unclear at first. In the 1970s, cable operators argued that they should be considered electronic publishers and be able to choose which channels and content to carry. Cable companies wanted the same “publishing” freedoms and legal protections that broadcast and print media enjoyed in selecting content. Just as local broadcasters could choose to carry local news or Jeopardy! at 6 P.M., cable companies wanted to choose what channels to carry.
At the time, the FCC argued the opposite: Cable systems were common carriers, providing services that do not get involved in content. Like telephone operators, who do not question the topics of personal conversations (“Hi, I’m the phone company, and what are you going to be talking about today?”), cable companies, the FCC argued, should offer at least part of their services on a first-
In 1979, the debate over this issue ended in the landmark Midwest Video case, when the U.S. Supreme Court upheld the rights of cable companies to determine channel content and defined the industry as a form of “electronic publishing.”17 Although the FCC could no longer mandate channels’ content, the Court said that communities could “request” access channels as part of contract negotiations in the franchising process. Access channels are no longer a requirement, but most cable companies continue to offer them in some form to remain on good terms with their communities.
Intriguingly, must-
Franchising Frenzy
After the Midwest Video decision, the future of cable programming was secure, and competition to obtain franchises to supply local cable service became intense. Essentially, a cable franchise is a mini-
During the franchising process, a city (or state) would outline its cable system needs and request bids from various cable companies. (Potential cable companies were prohibited from also owning broadcast stations or newspapers in the community.) In its bid, a company would make a list of promises to the city about construction schedules, system design, subscription rates, channel capacity, types of programming, financial backing, deadlines, and a franchise fee: the money the cable company would pay the city annually for the right to operate the local cable system. Lots of wheeling and dealing transpired in these negotiations, along with occasional corruption (e.g., paying off local city officials who voted on which company got the franchise), as few laws existed to regulate franchise negotiations. Often, battles over broken promises, unreasonable contracts, or escalating rates ended up in court.
Today, a federal cable policy act from 1984 dictates the franchise fees for most U.S. municipalities. This act helps cities and municipalities use such fees to establish and fund access channels for local government, educational, and community programming as part of their license agreement. For example, Groton, Massachusetts (population around ten thousand), has a cable contract with Charter Communications. According to the terms of the contract with Groton, Charter returned 4.25 percent of its revenue to the town (5 percent is the maximum a city can charge a cable operator). This money, which has amounted to about $100,000 a year, helped underwrite the city’s cable-
The Telecommunications Act of 1996
Between 1984 and 1996, lawmakers went back and forth on cable rates and rules, creating a number of cable acts. One Congress would try to end must-
The 1996 act has had a mixed impact on cable customers. Cable companies argued that it would lead to more competition and innovations in programming, services, and technology. But in fact, there is not extensive competition in cable. About 90 percent of communities in the United States still have only one local cable company. In these areas, cable rates have risen faster; and in communities with multiple cable providers, the competition makes a difference—
Still, the cable industry has delivered on some of its technology promises, investing nearly $150 billion in technological infrastructure between 1996 and 2009, with most of the funds used for installing high-