18
Behavioral and Experimental Economics 18
691
I magine you run the Centers for Disease Control and Prevention (CDC) located in Atlanta, Georgia. Your job is to keep America safe. Suddenly, an unusual disease breaks out in Florida. Your best scientists estimate that 600 Americans were exposed to the disease and will die if no government action is taken. You are given a choice between two programs to address this crisis.
Program 1 offers two possible responses to the crisis, each of which costs the same. Because of resource constraints, you can choose only one. Response A is a sure thing: It will definitely save 200 people. Response B is risky. It has a one-
Program 2 also offers two possible responses, each of which costs the same. Again, you can choose only one. With Response C, 400 people will die for certain. With Response D, there is a one-
Did you choose Response A for Program 1 and Response C for Program 2? You should have, because both responses are the same; they are only described differently. In either case, 200 people live and 400 people die with certainty. Similarly, Responses B and D are the same, but worded differently. With each response, there is a one-
18.1 When Human Beings Fail to Act the Way Economic Models Predict
18.2 Does Behavioral Economics Mean Everything We’ve Learned Is Useless?
18.3 Testing Economic Theories with Data: Experimental Economics
18.4 Conclusions and the Future of Microeconomics
1Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman, “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice,” Science 211, no. 4481 (1981): 453 – 458.
In a famous study, economic researchers asked people what response they would pick.1 With Program 1, 72% of the people chose Response A: Better to save 200 lives for certain with this option than gamble on saving more lives and risk saving no one with Response B. But when offered Program 2, 78% of the same people picked Response D. Their reasoning? How can you pick a response (C) in which 400 people die for sure when you can take a chance to save everyone? Remember that Responses A and C are the same: Response A saves 200 lives for certain (and thus 400 people die for certain), and in Response C, 400 people die for certain (and 200 people live for certain). By manipulating how these alternatives were framed, Amos Tversky and Daniel Kahneman (now a Nobel laureate) were able to alter the choices dramatically.
This outcome should not happen in a standard economic model. When we have thought about utility functions, costs, risks, and the like in the previous 17 chapters, decision making was never affected by how the choices were described. You prefer one bundle of goods to a second bundle or you don’t. Likewise, the cost of a particular level of output is calculated in the same manner for all levels. An economic model cannot explain why framing the problem in terms of lives saved versus lives lost should matter. Nor can it easily explain why companies price things in 99-
692
In recent years, economists have increasingly come to accept that, as great a job as standard economic models do in explaining the ways of the world, they sometimes fail badly when human psychology plays a role in people’s decision making.
behavioral economics
Branch of economics that incorporates insights from human psychology into models of economic behavior.
The nature of these models’ failures matters. If people and firms sometimes make mistakes and act differently from the perfectly rational, self-
Like the field of behavioral economics itself, this chapter is a bit different from the conventional microeconomics we’ve presented thus far. Instead of laying out specific models and showing you how to solve and apply them, this chapter examines some of the ways that economists and psychologists have expanded traditional economic models in an effort to better explain real-
In the second half of the chapter, we discuss the new ways economists have begun to test these behavioral economic models using actual experiments rather than traditional statistical methods like econometrics. We conclude the chapter and the book with a discussion of what behavioral economics means for the future of microeconomics.