40
CHAPTER 6
IS ADAM SMITH ROLLING OVER IN HIS GRAVE?
Perfect Competition, Efficiency, and the Father of Modern Economics
The celebrated eighteenth-
Adam Smith is often proclaimed the patriarch of modern economics. His most famous saying appeared in his 1776 book, The Wealth of Nations, in which he wrote that the individual decision maker
intends only his own gain; and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. . . . By pursuing his own interest, he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it.1
1 All quotes from Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations are from http:/
41
The notion of the market embodying an “invisible hand” by which self-
productive efficiency, meaning that firms minimize the average cost of producing their goods
allocative efficiency, meaning that each type of good is produced until the benefit from another unit of the good no longer exceeds the cost of producing another unit
distributive efficiency, meaning that goods go to those who value them the most
Remarkably, perfectly competitive markets achieve all three of these outcomes without your help as dictator. The following sections explain how that happens.
Under conditions that resemble pure or perfect competition as Smith imagined it, a large number of sellers sell the same good to a large number of buyers. Competitors can enter and leave the market easily, and everyone involved in the market has full information about what is available from whom at what price. Under these conditions, no consumer would pay more than the lowest available price; a firm that charges more than its competitors would get no business. Firms need not charge less than the equilibrium price because they can sell all they want at the equilibrium price (by virtue of demand equaling supply at equilibrium). Thus, each firm in a perfectly competitive industry ends up as a price taker, taking on the equilibrium price determined by the balance of supply and demand in the market.
Consider (as a real market that provides a break from routine) the on-
2 Assume they are the same for the purposes of this example. As with most things, you can find variations such as custom-
3 For example, there are 10 individual sellers and 68 “eBay stores” at www.ebay.com selling clown noses as of this writing. If you saw those stores earning worthwhile profits, you could start up a competing Internet “store” at almost no expense.
42
Firms seek economic profits, calculated by subtracting all costs, including the value of entrepreneurs’ time and the opportunity costs of using capital,4 from revenues. Entrepreneurs would accept 0 economic profits if necessary because they could not earn anything more in their next-
4 For example, even if the owners of a pizza shop have purchased their pizza oven, by using it, they forgo the opportunity to rent it out to someone else. Thus, the rental rate of an oven is a cost of using it for owners and renters alike.
Productive efficiency is achieved in perfectly competitive markets thanks to the ease of entry and exit by similar firms seeking economic profits. If ClownAntics.com isn’t using the lowest-
5 In this reality-
Remember that the supply curve represents the increasing marginal cost of producing each unit and that the demand curve represents the decreasing marginal value of each unit to consumers. At quantities of production below the equilibrium quantity, the demand curve is above the supply curve, indicating that the value of 1 more unit will exceed the cost. If the marginal value of another clown nose is $7 and the marginal cost is $3, more noses should be produced. However, it would be inefficient to produce beyond the equilibrium quantity because marginal value falls below marginal cost at the point of equilibrium. If another clown nose would cost $4 to make and it would be worth only $2, it would be unwise for society to allocate resources for another nose. It follows that to produce the equilibrium quantity is to produce all those units that are worth more than they cost to provide.
43
Like the equilibrium quantity, the equilibrium price is established at the intersection of supply and demand, meaning that the price equals both the marginal cost and the marginal value of the last nose sold. The condition for allocative efficiency is often stated as the equality of marginal cost and price because if the price that buyers are willing to pay is above the marginal cost, consumers must value another nose at more than the cost of making one, and too few clown noses are being made. Conversely, if buyers are not willing to pay a price as high as marginal cost, marginal value is below marginal cost and too many noses have been made.
The well-
6 These numbers are simply made up to comply with the law of supply (see Section 2 Economics by Example), which indicates that supply curves are upward sloping as a result of increasing marginal costs. The rate at which marginal costs increase is exaggerated here for the purpose of illustration.
7 It might be tempting to say that 4 noses should be produced because Dot would be willing to pay the $2 cost of the first nose, Clem would pay the $4 cost of the second nose, Ben would pay the $6 cost of the third nose, and Abe would pay the $8 cost of the fourth nose. Here’s the catch: No matter which clowns got which noses, the cost of making the fourth nose would be $8, and the combined benefit that the clowns receive would increase by only the $3 value that Dot receives when 4 rather than 3 are made. So making a fourth nose leads to a net loss of $8 − $3 = $5. Aside from this loss of efficiency, there’s also the problem that each good in a perfectly competitive market sells for the same price.
BUYER | BUYER’S MARGINAL VALUE | SELLER’S MARGINAL COST |
Abe | $12 | $ 2 |
Ben | $ 8 | $ 4 |
Clem | $ 6 | $ 6 |
Dot | $ 3 | $ 8 |
Ernest | $ 1 | $10 |
In our example, the equilibrium price will be $6 because that is the only price that equates supply and demand. As explained in the first section of this chapter, expect perfectly competitive firms to conform to the equilibrium price. Three of the clowns—
44
In contrast, imagine that a lottery rather than a market is used to allocate 3 noses. If names are drawn out of a hat, the recipients are equally likely to be any of the 5 clowns. Suppose Ben, Dot, and Ernest win the lottery. The total value created by the noses is the sum of the recipients’ marginal values: $8 + $3 + $1 = $12; this amount falls below the $12 + $8 + $6 = $26 worth of value obtained through the market allocation. In both cases the cost of producing 3 noses would be $2 + $4 + $6 = $12, but the net gain is the highest with the help of the market. Nonetheless, lotteries are common for allocating dorm rooms and student tickets for popular football games, among other valuable goods and services.
The previous examples demonstrate how buyers and sellers can enhance the well-
The cruelest of our revenue laws, I will venture to affirm, are mild and gentle, in comparison to some of those which the clamor of our merchants and manufacturers has extorted from the legislature, for the support of their own absurd and oppressive monopolies.
—Adam Smith, The Wealth of Nations
Although Smith venerated competitive markets, he abhorred monopoly power and trade secrets. In The Wealth of Nations, Smith wrote of “the mean rapacity, the monopolizing spirit, of merchants and manufacturers, who neither are, nor ought to be, the rulers of mankind.” The celebrated efficiency of competitive markets is jeopardized when individual sellers or buyers have market power, meaning that they can restrict supply and increase prices, or when any of the other conditions for perfect competition are violated.
Legal, technical, and economic barriers are among the deterrents to potential competitors in many markets, as a few examples will demonstrate. Pfizer, Inc., holds a patent on Viagra and ships the medication in bottles with radio frequency identification tags so that bottles coming from Pfizer can be distinguished from bottles coming from counterfeiters. In 2004, the De Beers Corporation, which controls much of the world’s diamond industry, paid a $10 million fine and pleaded guilty to criminal price fixing. Members of cartels, such as the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC), collude to reduce production and raise prices. The Recording Industry Association of America (RIAA) has sued individuals for illegally using peer-
45
In order for the equilibrium quantity of a good or service to be efficient, buyers and sellers must also bear, or internalize, the full cost and benefit of that product. Otherwise, the market equilibrium formed by the marginal costs and marginal benefits that market participants perceive differs from the true equilibrium of marginal costs and marginal benefits felt by society. Consider the following examples:
As the Anheuser-
The movie Supersize Me (2004) and the book Fast Food Nation (Schlosser, 2001) suggest that the overconsumption of fast food may cause more health problems than most consumers realize. If buyers don’t have full information on the health costs associated with their food, or if some of those costs are paid by other taxpayers via Medicaid or Medicare, then the demand curve will overstate the true benefits of fast food to society and, again, the equilibrium quantity will be too large.
If studying economics increases people’s contributions to society by making them wiser voters and more productive workers, the demand curve for economics classes will understate the value of economics to society, and the equilibrium number of students will be too small.
Such benefits and costs that aren’t borne by those making decisions about the products are called externalities. What is to be done when the assumptions of perfect competition are violated, as in these examples? Economists Richard Lipsey and Kelvin Lancaster advanced the general theory of second-
46
Smith believed that markets would overcome immoral behavior. He believed that benevolence would spring from market forces because, through trade, people gain in proportion to what they give and thus are prompted to develop ways to give more. But as with market failure, problems with morals have persisted in a way that Smith hoped they would not. Recent examples include the corporate ethics scandals at Arthur Andersen, Enron, Adelphia, ImClone, Citigroup, Qwest, WorldCom, and Tyco.
Tension exists between the desire for complete freedom and the desire to avoid the moral bankruptcy that threatens the efficiency of markets. The contemporary Adam Smith Institute is a self-
8 See www.adamsmith.org/
Smith wrote at length about the morality that underpinned his laissez-
Utilitarianism: Does this action bring the greatest good to the greatest number of people?
Ethical egoism: Is this action good for me?
The common good: Is this action good for society as a whole?
Virtue: Does this action reflect balance between vices?
Rights: Does this action respect the moral rights of everyone?
Kantianism: Would I want everyone to perform this action?
Justice: Is this action fair and just? Does it treat equals equally?
Role models: What would my hero do?
The newspaper test: Would I be embarrassed if this action appeared in a newspaper headline?
Smith would have us ruled neither by big government nor by big business. And he would have us behave in such ways as to win the approval of impartial observers. Would these observers approve of the exploitation of labor, the neglect of health and environmental concerns, exorbitant prices, or pressure on buyers to purchase items they don’t really need? Probably not—
47
Saying “Smith says” lends credibility to actions in much the same way that saying “Simon says” does in the popular children’s game of that name. Smith may not be rolling over in his grave in response to becoming a laissez-
Smith said that markets can achieve miraculous efficiency and that constraints on otherwise efficient markets can distort the incentives for socially optimal behavior. Smith would not have liked artificial controls on prices, quantities, or wages; nor would he have advocated government subsidies or tax breaks. However, the markets that should not be distorted are those that involve many informed sellers of an identical product and no barriers to entry or exit by competitors. Smith probably would have appreciated such measures as nutrition information labels on food packages, restrictions on monopoly power, and harsh punishments for deceptive advertising. Likewise, the enforcement of health and environmental standards that prevent firms from imposing pollution costs on society are in the spirit of Smith’s sensibilities.
Many people study supply and demand without understanding that only firms in perfectly competitive markets have supply curves. Monopolies will charge different prices for the same quantity, depending on what the demand curve looks like. Like the lessons of Adam Smith, much of what is learned in economics classes is contingent on perfectly competitive markets. Given market imperfections, individuals should relish free markets within reason while maintaining high moral standards and accepting measures that deal with market failure in order to attain the highest possible level of social well-
What markets in your local economy most closely resemble Adam Smith’s ideal of perfect competition?
Summarize Adam Smith’s message about the potential virtues of free markets.
What characteristics does the hamburger market in your area share with a perfectly competitive industry? What conditions for perfect competition does it violate?
Given that the Justice Department and the Federal Trade Commission seek to promote competition between firms, what arguments do you suppose were used to gain their acceptance of the Kmart–