75
CHAPTER 11
WHY NOT SPLIT THE CHECK?
A Briefing on Market Failure
Last Friday, somewhere near you, a group of students slurped root beers at a popular burger joint. Frosted mugs cluttered the table like miniature Manhattan skyscrapers. Gossip and wisecracks filled the air. When the check arrived, a student in blue jeans and a black concert t-
Ideal market conditions yield efficient allocations of inputs and outputs. Market failure is the reason why some markets do not bring about the best outcomes for society. As explained in Section 11 Economics by Example, perfectly competitive firms achieve market efficiency by equating marginal costs and marginal benefits. This chapter provides a constructive overview of the sources of market failure: externalities, imperfect competition, imperfect information, and public goods. Each of these sources receives further mention later in the book: Imperfect information is the focus of Chapter 12; imperfect competition is central to the issues in Chapters 13 and 14; public goods are the topic of Chapter 18; and externalities are reprised in Chapter 29. As you’re about to learn, some of the solutions to market failure are as simple as paying for your own root beers.
76
Externalities are costs or benefits felt beyond, or external to, the people causing them. When you get a flu shot, you create positive externalities because other people won’t catch the flu from you. When you drive a car, you create the negative externalities of road congestion and air pollution. To emit toxins into the air or water during a manufacturing process, smoke in public, play loud music, catch fish that other fishers are angling for, or paint your house a dreadful shade of green is to impose external costs—
You may not think of root beer as a potential source of negative externalities, but when you buy a root beer with a group that is splitting the check equally, you impose a cost on everyone in that group.1 Suppose a root beer costs $2 and you have 10 people in your group. Suppose also that diminishing marginal utility leads you to value your first 5 root beers at $3, $2.50, $1.25, $0.50, and $0.10, respectively. If you were not splitting the check, you would buy 2 root beers for $2 each—
1 For more on the negative externality problem with splitting the check, and for empirical evidence of the problem, see www.gsb.uchicago.edu/
The problem grows because everyone in the group faces the same incentive to overconsume. If your friends share your preference for root beer, each of the 10 friends will consume 4 beverages, bringing the total bill up to $80. Each friend’s share of the bill will be $8—
Externality problems can be resolved if ways can be found to have everyone internalize, or feel for themselves, the full costs or benefits of their decisions. In the root beer example, that means having everyone pay his or her own bill. The negative externalities from goods such as gasoline, cigarettes, and alcohol are internalized if excise taxes (taxes levied on particular goods such as these) approximate the associated external costs. A solution to the underconsumption that accompanies positive externalities is for the government to subsidize purchases, as is the case for flu shots as well as education, tree planting, and clean energy.
77
Because goods creating positive externalities are underconsumed and goods creating negative externalities are overconsumed from a societal standpoint, another solution is to require people to purchase the efficient quantity of these goods. It is common for governments to require a particular number of childhood immunizations and education through high school while limiting the volume of power plant emissions and the number of pets that can be kept in a household. For example, in the interest of neighborhood serenity and sanitation, no resident in the city of Grand Junction, Colorado, may keep more than 3 adult pets, such as dogs or cats. Chapter 26 elaborates on the role of government and explains how the enforcement of private property rights can assist with externality problems.
Hawaiian shirts sell for $30 and up in the gift shop of the Honolulu International Airport. In downtown Honolulu, the Daiei supermarket sells similar Hawaiian shirts for $14. Both places sell shirts that are made in Hawaii at comparable costs; most of the price differential stems from differing levels of competition. Daiei faces competition from hundreds of other shirt sellers, and if the managers were to raise their prices significantly above marginal cost, competitors would undercut their prices and steal away some of their customers and profits. That’s how prices in competitive environments are brought down to approximately the marginal cost of production. When price equals marginal cost, consumers keep buying until their marginal benefit equals the price, and because price equals marginal cost, the efficiency condition of marginal cost equaling marginal benefit is satisfied. As explained in further detail in Section 11 Economics by Example, competitive markets can achieve productive, allocative, and distributive efficiency.
Prices are higher at the airport because the number of sellers is limited2 and their clientele is captive. Many of the airport customers are leaving the island and have no choice but to make any additional purchases at the airport gift shop. That gives the gift shop market power—the ability to influence prices—
2 It is common for airports to offer exclusive “master concession” agreements to retailers. For example, HMSHost Corp. owns master concession rights for all food and beverage operations at Honolulu International Airport. See http:/
78
McDonald’s Restaurant and Doug’s Restaurant are both located on North Canal Boulevard in Thibodaux, Louisiana. Why would visitors to Cajun country eat at McDonald’s when they could encounter local cuisine at Doug’s? One reason involves imperfect information, which exists when at least one buyer doesn’t know the true benefit of a good or service or at least one seller doesn’t know the true cost of providing a good or service. As far as visitors know, Doug’s may or may not be a good place to eat. There is relatively little uncertainty about a meal at McDonald’s because most visitors know exactly what’s on the menu and how it will taste. The additional investment of time and money that customers must make to determine food quality at an unknown restaurant stands in the way of competition from new, no-
When buyers and sellers don’t share the same information, the problem of asymmetric information arises. As explained in Chapter 5, those in the marriage market use ease of attraction as a signal of the unseen qualities of a potential mate. Employers and shoppers likewise use college degrees, grades, name brands, and prices as imperfect signals of quality among workers and products when perfect information is not available. Nobel laureate George Akerlof pointed out that there is asymmetric information between buyers and sellers of used cars: Sellers know things about the quality of their cars that potential buyers do not. Suppose that used cars are either good or bad and that good used cars are worth $20,000, whereas bad used cars are worth $10,000. Given the uncertainty about whether a car will be a “lemon” (bad), buyers are unlikely to pay $20,000 for a used car. If, in the buyer’s estimation, there is a 20 percent chance that the car is a lemon and an 80 percent chance that it’s worth $20,000, the expected value of the car (the sum of each probability times the outcome that occurs with that probability) is (0.2)($10,000) + (0.8)($20,000) = $18,000. Thus, sellers of good used cars won’t get fair prices for their cars, but sellers of lemons will. The result is that owners of good used cars are more likely to hold on to their cars and the used car market may be made up primarily of lemons.
In response to the risk that the market for used cars might become a market for lemons, many buyers of used cars (and homes and boats) invest in a professional evaluation of their contemplated purchase to try to gain more of the information held by the seller. Car buyers are also wise to request a vehicle identification number (VIN) check on their car at a Web site such as www.carfax.com, which will reveal information on odometer readings, the number of previous owners, any major accidents in the vehicle’s past, and similar potential problems that sellers know about and buyers otherwise don’t.
79
Adverse selection occurs when it costs varying amounts of money to serve different customers but sellers cannot distinguish between high-
Moral hazard is the tendency for those with insurance against a problem to take fewer precautions to avoid that problem. Knowing that a hospital stay can cost $2,000 or more per day, people with insurance may be more likely to take up skydiving than are people who have to shoulder their entire medical bill themselves. Laid-
Clearly, the solutions to imperfect information are themselves imperfect and costly. Car and human checkups intended to level the informational playing field sometimes do not. High copayments place a financial burden on the poor. Only a 100 percent copayment would bring decision makers to internalize the full costs of their behaviors, and that would eliminate the risk-
A handful of spy satellites spin 100 miles above the earth, recording a constant video stream of activities below. These billion-
3 See www.spacetoday.org/
80
A few relevant terms are useful in explaining why this is the case. A good or service is nonrival in consumption if 1 person’s consumption of it does not affect anyone else’s consumption of it. A street band is nonrival in consumption because 1 passerby’s enjoyment of the music doesn’t prevent others from enjoying it. In contrast, shoes are rival in consumption because if 1 person is wearing them another person cannot. A good or service is nonexcludable if it is impossible to prevent other people from benefiting as long as 1 person is benefiting from it. A streetlight is nonexcludable because, if it is lighting the way for 1 driver, other drivers can benefit from the same light. Dorm rooms are excludable because you can lock your door and prevent others from entering. Goods and services that are both nonrival in consumption and nonexcludable are called public goods.
The challenge of creating the efficient number of spy satellites, as with street bands and streetlights, is that they are public goods. Everyone can benefit from them no matter who pays for them. Thus, the temptation is to be a free rider and enjoy the benefits of someone else’s expenditures. Some street bands appear because some people give them tips, but more would appear if everyone who enjoyed the music chipped in. If the Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) went from door to door asking everyone to pitch in to pay for the next satellite, it would be rational from an individual standpoint for many people to contribute less than their fair share of the price in hopes that others would purchase the satellites to the benefit of all. The result is that private markets for public goods generally don’t bring about the efficient quantity of the goods in question.
A common solution to the free-
Entire books have been written about each of these types of market failure. In terms of the primary example in this chapter, it is interesting to note that the local root beer stand isn’t the only place where the check is split. In 2005, health-
4 See http:/
5 See www.econlib.org/
81
This chapter highlights situations in which market incentives and the decisions they drive run afoul of efficiency. When individuals don’t bear the cost of their personal consumption choices, the incentive is to buy too much of goods and services that place burdens on others and too little of goods and services that benefit others. When barriers to competition exist, people can expect prices above marginal cost and lost opportunities to produce goods that are valued beyond their production cost. When information is imperfect, people cannot respond appropriately to true marginal costs and marginal benefits. And when goods are nonrival in consumption and nonexcludable, people have incentives to minimize expenditures on these public goods in hopes of free riding on the purchases of others. These problems prevent consumption from continuing until the benefit from another unit no longer exceeds the cost; as a result, the market fails to create all the net benefits that it otherwise could.
If someone smokes cigarettes in the desert and no one else is there to smell the smoke, does the smoking create a negative externality? Why or why not?
To what extent do people consider only the private costs and overlook the social costs of their actions? Do you consider the burden you impose on others when you and your friends order root beers and split the check? Do you consider the burden you impose on others when you order new shoes, thus creating production, transportation, and disposal externalities? Do you think about the congestion and pollution you create when you decide how many car trips to take?
75
As a deterrent to burglary, you could install alarms around your home that help the police catch criminals or install a fence around your home that keeps intruders out. In terms of crime (and disregarding the attractiveness of the fence), which of these deterrents might create positive externalities? Which might create negative externalities? Which method of crime deterrence might a neighborhood association want to subsidize? Why?
Do you ever participate in adverse selection? How might adverse selection cause you to pay higher interest rates on your credit card balances?
Are you ever affected by moral hazard? How might moral hazard influence your decision to go water-
Why do you suppose there are 50 McDonald’s restaurants within 10 miles of the tourism mecca of Orlando, Florida, but only 17 within the same distance of Oxnard, California (a town of similar size)? Hint: One would expect this difference in the number of golden arches even if the same number of restaurant meals were eaten in each city.