Deflation

Before World War II, deflation—a falling aggregate price level—was almost as common as inflation. (We introduced deflation in Chapter 21.) In fact, the U.S. consumer price index on the eve of World War II was 30% lower than it had been in 1920. After World War II, inflation became the norm in all countries. But in the 1990s, deflation reappeared in Japan and proved difficult to reverse. Concerns about potential deflation played a crucial role in U.S. monetary policy in the early 2000s and again in the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis.

Why is deflation a problem? And why is it hard to end?

Debt Deflation

Deflation, like inflation, produces both winners and losers—but in the opposite direction. Due to the falling price level, a dollar in the future has a higher real value than a dollar today. So lenders, who are owed money, gain under deflation because the real value of borrowers’ payments increases. Borrowers lose because the real burden of their debt rises.

In a famous analysis at the beginning of the Great Depression, Irving Fisher (who first analyzed the Fisher effect of expected inflation on interest rates, described in Chapter 25) claimed that the effects of deflation on borrowers and lenders can worsen an economic slump. Deflation, in effect, takes real resources away from borrowers and redistributes them to lenders.

Debt deflation is the reduction in aggregate demand arising from the increase in the real burden of outstanding debt caused by deflation.

Fisher argued that borrowers, who lose from deflation, are typically short of cash and will be forced to cut their spending sharply when their debt burden rises. Lenders, however, are unlikely to increase spending sharply when the values of the loans they own rise. The overall effect, said Fisher, is that deflation reduces aggregate demand, deepening an economic slump, which, in a vicious circle, may lead to further deflation. The effect of deflation in reducing aggregate demand, known as debt deflation, probably played a significant role in the Great Depression.

Effects of Expected Deflation

Like expected inflation, expected deflation affects the nominal interest rate. Look back at Figure 25-7, which demonstrated how expected inflation affects the equilibrium interest rate. In Figure 25-7, the equilibrium nominal interest rate is 4% if the expected inflation rate is 0%. Clearly, if the expected inflation rate is −3%—if the public expects deflation at 3% per year—the equilibrium nominal interest rate will be 1%.

There is a zero bound on the nominal interest rate: it cannot go below zero.

But what would happen if the expected rate of inflation is −5%? Would the nominal interest rate fall to −1%, in which lenders are paying borrowers 1% on their debt? No. Nobody would lend money at a negative nominal rate of interest, because they could do better by simply holding cash. This illustrates what economists call the zero bound on the nominal interest rate: it cannot go below zero.

This zero bound can limit the effectiveness of monetary policy. Suppose the economy is depressed, with output below potential output and the unemployment rate above the natural rate. Normally the central bank can respond by cutting interest rates so as to increase aggregate demand. If the nominal interest rate is already zero, however, the central bank cannot push it down any further. Banks refuse to lend and consumers and firms refuse to spend because, with a negative inflation rate and a 0% nominal interest rate, holding cash yields a positive real return: with falling prices, a given amount of cash buys more over time. Any further increases in the monetary base will either be held in bank vaults or held as cash by individuals and firms, without being spent.

The economy is in a liquidity trap when conventional monetary policy is ineffective, because nominal interest rates are up against the zero bound.

A situation in which conventional monetary policy to fight a slump—cutting interest rates—can’t be used because nominal interest rates are up against the zero bound is known as a liquidity trap. A liquidity trap can occur whenever there is a sharp reduction in demand for loanable funds—which is exactly what happened during the Great Depression. Figure 31-14 shows the interest rate on short-term U.S. government debt from 1920 to 2014. As you can see, from 1933 until World War II brought a full economic recovery, the U.S. economy was either close to or up against the zero bound. After World War II, when inflation became the norm around the world, the zero bound largely vanished as a problem, as the public came to expect inflation rather than deflation.

The Zero Bound in U.S. History This figure shows U.S. short-term interest rates, specifically the interest rate on three-month Treasury bills, from 1920 to 2014. As shown by the shaded area at left, for much of the 1930s, interest rates were very close to zero, leaving little room for expansionary monetary policy. After World War II, persistent inflation generally kept interest rates well above zero. However, in late 2008, in the wake of the housing bubble bursting and the financial crisis, the interest rate on three-month Treasury bills was again virtually zero.Sources: National Bureau of Economic Research; Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

However, the recent history of the Japanese economy, shown in Figure 31-15, provides a modern illustration of the problem of deflation and the liquidity trap. Japan experienced a huge boom in the prices of both stocks and real estate in the late 1980s, then saw both bubbles burst. The result was a prolonged period of economic stagnation, the so-called Lost Decades, which gradually reduced the inflation rate and eventually led to persistent deflation.

Japan’s Lost Decades A prolonged economic slump in Japan led to deflation from the late 1990s on. The Bank of Japan responded by cutting interest rates—but eventually ran up against the zero bound.Source: Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

In an effort to fight the weakness of the economy, the Bank of Japan—the equivalent of the Federal Reserve—repeatedly cut interest rates. Eventually, it arrived at the ZIRP: the zero interest rate policy. The call money rate, the equivalent of the U.S. federal funds rate, was literally set equal to zero. Because the economy was still depressed, it would have been desirable to cut interest rates even further. But that wasn’t possible: Japan was up against the zero bound.

In the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis, the world’s most important central banks—the U.S. Federal Reserve and the European Central Bank—found themselves facing much the same problems the Bank of Japan had faced since the 1990s: the economies they were trying to manage remained depressed despite policy interest rates close to zero, and inflation was persistently below target. As of 2014, neither the United States nor the euro area was experiencing actual deflation, but as the following Economics in Action describes, Europe was getting alarmingly close.

!worldview! ECONOMICS in Action: Is Europe Turning Japanese?

Is Europe Turning Japanese?

In the aftermath of the 2008 financial crisis, officials at the Federal Reserve were deeply worried about the possibility of “Japanification”—that is, they worried that, like Japan since the 1990s, the United States might find itself stuck in a deflationary trap. To avoid this possibility, they took some extraordinary measures, notably the large-scale purchases of assets—so-called “quantitative easing”—described in Chapter 30. By 2014, it seemed that the danger of deflation in the United States had at least somewhat receded.

Trouble in Europe, 2008–2014Source: Eurostat.

But Europe was a different story. Where the U.S. recovery from the recession of 2007–2009 was steady, if disappointingly slow, the euro area, held back by debt crises, slid back into recession in late 2011. Growth resumed in 2013, but as you can see from panel (a) of Figure 31-16, it barely made a dent in high unemployment. And as panel (b) of Figure 31-16 shows, in 2013–2014 inflation began sliding below 1 percent, leading to worries that Europe was on track to replicate Japan’s lost decades. While Europe was not yet experiencing actual deflation as of 2014, it was, as the International Monetary Fund put it, suffering from “lowflation”—inflation persistently below target—and this created many of the same problems. In particular, lower-than-expected inflation was worsening the problems of highly indebted nations, like Portugal, Spain, and Greece.

And like the Bank of Japan a number of years earlier, the European Central Bank was finding it hard to devise an effective answer to the slide toward deflation. In June 2014, it took the extraordinary step of reducing one of its key policy, rates, the interest rate it pays on deposits of private banks, to minus 0.1 percent—that is, it began actually charging banks a fee for holding their money. But even this didn’t seem to be doing much to boost the economy.

Quick Review

  • Unexpected deflation helps lenders and hurts borrowers. This can lead to debt deflation, which has a contractionary effect on aggregate demand.

  • Deflation makes it more likely that interest rates will end up against the zero bound. When this happens, the economy is in a liquidity trap, and monetary policy is ineffective.

31-4

  1. Question 16.8

    Why won’t anyone lend money at a negative nominal rate of interest? How can this pose problems for monetary policy?

Solution appears at back of book.

Licenses to Print Money

People sometimes talk about profitable companies as having a “license to print money.” Well, the British firm De La Rue actually does. In 1930, De La Rue, printer of items such as postage stamps, expanded into the money-printing business, producing banknotes for the then-government of China. Today it is the largest manufacturer of banknotes, producing the currencies of about 150 countries, from the United Kingdom to Fiji.

De La Rue’s business received some unexpected attention in 2011 when Muammar Gaddafi, the dictator who had ruled Libya from 1969 until 2011, was fighting to suppress a fierce popular uprising. To finance his efforts, he turned to seignorage, ordering around $1.5 billion worth of Libyan dinars printed. But Libyan banknotes weren’t printed in Libya; they were printed in Britain at one of De La Rue’s facilities. The British government, an enemy of the Gaddafi regime, seized the new banknotes before they could be flown to Libya, refusing to release them until Gaddafi had been overthrown.

Why do so many countries turn to private companies like De La Rue and its main rivals, the German firm Giesecke & Devrient and the French firm Oberthur, to print their currencies? The short answer is that printing money isn’t as easy as it sounds—producing high-quality banknotes that are hard to counterfeit requires highly specialized equipment and expertise. This is particularly true now that many countries are turning to banknotes printed of polymer, which are more durable and harder to counterfeit than paper money. In 2014, De La Rue was chosen to produce the next generation of British banknotes, the first ones to be made of plastic.

Actually, De La Rue has had its own problems with quality control: a scandal erupted in 2010, when it emerged that one of its plants had been producing defective security paper and that employees had covered up the problems. Nonetheless, many countries will surely continue relying on expert private firms to produce their currencies.

QUESTIONS FOR THOUGHT

  1. Question 16.9

    ZbQhIjLGPG5GK+oJ8pCv4gzj5dTRyyQERDUMTbjx7ivCXXwiYflwsrctQjkdJXrVdetw4FvVyIp6W5PlSQqxYPLfBD3ABd7Ew44D2BI50fmm1jkN96CqMxZmCkpQtTS3BitJVIgoMZI=
    How can a government obtain revenue by printing money when someone else actually prints the money?
  2. Question 16.10

    iK+118rg8vCwiZIOdneC8MbhIl6aHS2tFE7Sojhgqd6kOZToI7aiSApkxfGsxX94E8XSJdvn+D2aSvR3jsYBt1RSGGsumOpazvS2tm3dXH04GLk7
    Why, exactly, would Gaddafi have resorted to the printing press in early 2011?
  3. Question 16.11

    8hX4mut6p5GViZTW0L6xEiiKMda+Q8PQBwelvjPQkTA7LzNdt+yHQ81OMDVQJakZn4YLC/b2E+s9KLX+zbW+foFNm4YN9Vy+jrW86ICIjQEZ9ZL1dsJqcmgPbJc=
    Were there risks to the Libyan economy in releasing those dinars to the new government?