THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME AND WEALTH

income A flow measure reflecting the funds received by individuals or households over a period of time, usually a week, month, or year.

wealth A stock measure of an individual’s or family’s assets, net of liabilities, at a given point in time.

Income is a flow, wealth is a stock. Income measures the receipt of funds by individuals or households over time, usually a week, month, or year. Income is a flow of funds measure. Wealth, in contrast, measures a family’s assets net of liabilities, at a given point in time. You may earn a certain income in 2017, but your net wealth is measured on a specific day, say, December 31, 2017. Many people were wealthy on January 1, 2007, but after suffering the ravages of a falling housing and stock market, they were considerably less wealthy on July 1, 2009.

You can be wealthy with low income if you do not work and your assets are in homes, stocks, and bonds that earn little to no interest or dividends. Alternatively, you can have little wealth, yet a high income, if you are like a rookie professional ballplayer who earns a seven-figure salary but has not yet accumulated assets.

Life Cycle Effects

Family and individual incomes vary significantly over the course of people’s lives. Young people just starting their careers often earn only a modest income. Over their working careers, they become more experienced and their salaries increase, with income peaking roughly between the ages of 45 and 55. At some point between ages 45 and 60, family size begins to decline as the kids grow up and leave home. As people approach 60, income begins declining, while household saving rises as they prepare for retirement. Incomes decline with retirement, but then again, so do family responsibilities.

One result of this economic life cycle is that an aging society can expect to see changes in income distribution as a greater number of households falls into lower income brackets. The life cycle also has implications for the economic effects of immigration. Newcomers to the United States often possess limited skills; therefore, when the country admits more immigrants, it can expect more low-income households. The children of immigrants, however, move up the income distribution ladder.

The Distribution of Income

functional distribution of income The distribution of income for resources or factors of production (land, labor, capital, and entrepreneurial ability).

Income distribution can be considered from several different perspectives. First, we can look at the functional distribution of income, which splits income among the inputs (factors) of production. The functional distribution for the United States between 1929 and 2015 is shown in Table 1.

TABLE 1 FUNCTIONAL DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME (ABSOLUTE DOLLARS IN BILLIONS, NUMBERS IN PARENTHESES ARE PERCENTAGES OF TOTAL INCOME)
Year Wages Proprietor’s Income Rent Corporate Profits Net Interest
1929 51.1 (60.3) 14.9 (17.6) 4.9 (5.8) 9.2 (10.8) 4.7 (5.5)
1940 52.1 (65.4) 12.9 (16.2) 2.7 (3.4) 8.7 (10.9) 3.3 (4.1)
1950 154.8 (65.5) 38.4 (16.3) 7.1 (3.0) 33.7 (14.3) 2.3 (1.0)
1960 296.4 (69.4) 51.9 (12.1) 16.2 (3.8) 52.3 (12.2) 10.7 (2.5)
1970 617.2 (73.7) 79.8 (9.5) 20.3 (2.4) 81.6 (9.7) 38.4 (4.6)
1980 1651.7 (73.6) 177.6 (7.9) 31.3 (1.4) 198.5 (8.8) 183.9 (8.2)
1990 3351.7 (72.2) 381.0 (8.2) 49.1 (1.1) 408.6 (8.8) 452.4 (9.7)
2000 5715.2 (71.6) 715.0 (9.0) 141.6 (1.8) 876.4 (11.0) 532.7 (6.7)
2010 8093.9 (69.3) 1059.3 (9.1) 425.0 (3.6) 1435.1 (12.3) 661.9 (5.7)
2015 9737.1 (67.8) 1400.1 (9.8) 663.6 (4.6) 2049.9 (14.3) 508.3 (3.5)
Table 15.1: TABLE 1 FUNCTIONAL DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME (ABSOLUTE DOLLARS IN BILLIONS, NUMBERS IN PARENTHESES ARE PERCENTAGES OF TOTAL INCOME)

Data from Bureau of Economic Analysis.

Labor’s share of national income rose from 1929 to the 1970s but fell each decade after. The share of income going to small businesses, called “proprietor’s income,” has declined over this period, but has stabilized at slightly under 10%. Rental income’s share fell from 1960 to 1990, but has since grown back to over 4%. The share accruing to corporate profits has increased in recent years to over 14%.

As Table 1 illustrates, the biggest fluctuations in income share have been associated with income from interest earned by individuals and firms, and are caused largely by changes in interest rates. It declined until 1960, then rose until the 1990s, before falling again in the last two decades.

399

Personal or Family Distribution of Income

personal or family distribution of income The distribution of income to individuals or family groups (typically quintiles, or fifths, of the population).

When most people use the expression “the distribution of income,” they typically mean personal or family distribution of income. This distributional measure is concerned with how much income, in percentage terms, goes to specific segments of the population.

To analyze personal and family income distribution, the Census Bureau essentially arrays households from the lowest incomes to the highest. It then splits these households into quintiles, or fifths, from the lowest 20% of households to the highest 20%. After totaling and averaging household incomes for each quintile, the Census Bureau computes the percentage of income flowing to each quintile.

Today, the United States contains approximately 125 million households. Therefore, the 25 million households with the lowest incomes compose the bottom quintile, and the 25 million households with the highest incomes compose the top quintile. Because much of the country’s income is concentrated at the top, the Census Bureau breaks down the highest quintile further, showing the percentage of income flowing to the richest 5% and 1% of the population.

Table 2 shows the official income distribution estimates for the United States since 1970. These estimates are based on money income before taxes and do not include the value of noncash benefits, such as food stamps, public housing, Medicaid, or employer-provided benefits.

TABLE 2 SHARE OF AGGREGATE INCOME RECEIVED BY EACH HOUSEHOLD QUINTILE: 1970–2014 AND THE GINI COEFFICIENT
Year Lowest Second Third Fourth Highest Top 5% Top 1% Gini Coefficient
1970 4.1 10.8 17.4 24.5 43.3 19.9 8.5 0.394
1975 4.4 10.5 17.1 24.8 43.2 20.1 8.2 0.397
1980 4.3 10.3 16.9 24.9 43.7 20.2 8.8 0.403
1985 4.0 9.7 16.3 24.6 45.3 23.0 11.2 0.419
1990 3.9 9.6 15.9 24.0 46.6 23.9 11.9 0.428
1995 3.7 9.1 15.2 23.3 48.7 25.5 12.2 0.450
2000 3.6 8.9 14.9 23.0 49.6 26.5 17.3 0.462
2005 3.4 8.6 14.6 23.0 50.4 27.1 17.4 0.469
2010 3.3 8.5 14.6 23.4 50.3 27.8 18.5 0.470
2014 3.1 8.2 14.3 23.2 51.2 29.2 19.3 0.480
Table 15.2: TABLE 2 SHARE OF AGGREGATE INCOME RECEIVED BY EACH HOUSEHOLD QUINTILE: 1970–2014 AND THE GINI COEFFICIENT

Data from U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey, Annual Social and Economic Supplement (Washington, DC: U.S. Government Printing Office), 2015.

Note that if the income distribution were perfectly equal, all quintiles would receive 20% of aggregate income. A quick look at these income distributions over the past four decades suggests that our distribution of income has been growing more unequal. Specifically, the share of income received by the highest quintile has steadily risen since 1970, while the share of income received by each of the four other quintiles has steadily fallen since 1970. Even more notable is how the income flowing to the top 1% has increased the most, with that share of income more than doubling since 1970. Keep in mind that these numbers ignore taxes and transfers (direct payment to households such as welfare and food stamps) that temper income inequality somewhat.

400

Still, incomes of the richest Americans have fared best over the last generation, and one piece of evidence has been the meteoric rise in CEO salaries. Adjusting for inflation, the average salary of a CEO increased 8-fold since 1978, while real wages for workers have barely changed. Such stark differences in worker compensation contributed to the growth of the Occupy movement in recent years and its claims against the power held by the richest 1%.

Compressing distribution data into quintiles allows us to see how distribution has evolved. Economists have developed two primary measures that allow comparisons to be drawn with ease across time and between countries. These measures are Lorenz curves and the Gini coefficient.

Lorenz Curves

Lorenz curve A graph showing the cumulative distribution of income or wealth. Households are measured on the horizontal axis while income or wealth is measured on the vertical axis.

A Lorenz curve cumulates households of various income levels on the horizontal axis, and relates this to their cumulated share of total income on the vertical axis. Figure 1, for simplicity, shows a two-person economy. Assume that each person earns 50% of the total income, or that income is divided evenly. Point a in Figure 1 marks this point, resulting in the equal distribution curve 0ac.

401

Figure 15.1: FIGURE 1 LORENZ CURVES (TWO-PERSON ECONOMY)
image
Figure 15.1: If both people in this two-person economy earn 50% of the total income, income will be distributed perfectly equally, shown by the equal distribution curve 0ac. Curve 0bc represents the same economy in which the low-income person earns 25% of the total income and the upper-income person earns 75%. This curve is skewed to the right, indicating an unequal distribution. The most extreme distribution between these two individuals (0% and 100%) is represented by the Lorenz curve 0dc.

The second curve in Figure 1 shows a two-person economy where the low-income person earns 25% of the total income and the upper-income person receives 75% (point b). This graph is skewed to the right (curve 0bc), indicating an unequal distribution. If this two-person income distribution were as unequal as possible (0% and 100%), the Lorenz curve would be equal to curve 0dc.

Figure 2 and its accompanying table offer more realistic Lorenz curves for income and wealth data for the United States in the year 2014. The quintile income distribution in the second column of the table is cumulated in the third column and plotted in Figure 2. (To cumulate a quintile means to add its percentage of income to the percentages earned by all lower quintiles.)

Figure 15.2: FIGURE 2 LORENZ CURVES
image
Figure 15.2: The graph shows the most recent Lorenz curves for income and wealth in the United States. The quintile distribution of income, found in the second column of the accompanying table, is cumulated in the third column and then plotted as a Lorenz curve. Notice how wealth is much more unequally distributed than income.
Data from the U.S. Census Bureau.

In Figure 2, for instance, the share of income received by the lowest fifth is 3.1%; it is plotted as point a. Next, the lowest two quintiles are summed (3.1 + 8.2 = 11.3) and plotted as point b. The process continues until all quintiles have been plotted to create the Lorenz curve.

Figure 2 also plots the Lorenz curve for wealth; it shows how wealth is much more unequally distributed than income. The wealthiest 20% of Americans control nearly 90% of wealth, even though they earn only half of all income.

402

Gini Coefficient

Gini coefficient A measure of income inequality defined as the area between the Lorenz curve and the equal distribution line divided by the total area below the equal distribution line.

Lorenz curves provide a good graphical summation of income (or wealth) distributions, but they can be inconvenient to use when comparing distributions between different countries or across time. Economists prefer to use one number to represent the inequality of an economy’s income (or wealth) distribution: the Gini coefficient.

The Gini coefficient provides a measure of the position of the Lorenz curve. It is calculated by dividing the area between the Lorenz curve and the equal distribution line by the area below the equal distribution line. In Figure 3, the Gini coefficient is the ratio of area A to area (A + B).

Figure 15.3: FIGURE 3 THE GINI COEFFICIENT
image
Figure 15.3: The Gini coefficient is a measure of income inequality, defined as the ratio of the area between the Lorenz curve and the equal distribution line, and the total area below the equal distribution line. Thus, the Gini coefficient is equal to the ratio between area A and area (A + B). If distribution were equal, area A would be zero, and the Gini coefficient would equal zero. If distribution were as unequal as possible, area B would disappear; thus, the Gini coefficient would be 1.

If the distribution were equal, area A would disappear (equal zero); thus, the Gini coefficient would be zero. If the distribution were as unequal as possible, with one individual or household earning all national income, area B would disappear; thus, the Gini coefficient would be 1.

As a rule, the lower the coefficient, the more equal the distribution; the higher the coefficient, the more unequal. Looking back at the last column in Table 2, the Gini coefficient confirms that the basic income distribution has become more unequal since 1970. The Gini coefficient has risen from 0.394 in 1970 to 0.480 in 2014.

The Impact of Redistribution

In the United States, there is a vast array of income redistribution policies, including the progressive income tax (where those with higher incomes pay a higher rate than those with lower incomes), housing subsidies, and other transfer payments such as Medicaid and Medicare, Social Security, and traditional welfare programs. Remember that the income distribution data in Table 2 excluded such government-provided cash and noncash benefits, and the effects of taxation.

Figure 4 provides an estimate of the impact progressive taxes and transfer payments (cash and in-kind) had on the income distribution in the United States. As we would expect, distribution became more equal: The Gini coefficient declined from 0.480, according to the official measure using gross income, to 0.391 after adjusting for taxes and transfer payments.

Figure 15.4: FIGURE 4 LORENZ CURVES FOR THE UNITED STATES: MONEY INCOME AND INCOME ADJUSTED FOR TAXES AND TRANSFER PAYMENTS
image
Figure 15.4: These Lorenz curves provide an estimate of the impact progressive taxes and transfer payments (cash and in-kind) had on income distribution in the United States. As one would expect, distribution becomes more equal once taxes and transfer payments are taken into account. In this case, the Gini coefficient declined from 0.480 to 0.391.
Data from the U.S. Census Bureau.

403

Table 3 provides some examples of how income distribution varies around the world. Income in European countries is generally more equally distributed than in the United States, while many South American countries have more unequal distributions.

TABLE 3 GINI COEFFICIENTS FOR VARIOUS COUNTRIES, 2014
Country Gini Coefficient Country Gini Coefficient
Australia 0.349 Italy 0.352
Bolivia 0.481 Japan 0.321
Brazil 0.529 Mexico 0.481
Canada 0.337 New Zealand 0.362
Chile 0.505 South Africa 0.634
China 0.421 Spain 0.359
Denmark 0.291 Sweden 0.273
France 0.331 United Kingdom 0.326
Israel 0.428 United States 0.480
Table 15.3: TABLE 3 GINI COEFFICIENTS FOR VARIOUS COUNTRIES, 2014

Data from World Bank, World Development Indicators (Washington, D.C.: World Bank), 2015.

404

image
Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, is one of the most beautiful cities in the world, but it also has some of the largest slums in the world.
Morten Elm/Dreamstime.com
David Davis/Dreamstime.com

Redistribution policies are the subject of intense debates. Those on the political right argue that differences in income are the natural result of a market system in which different individuals possess different personal endowments, schooling, and ambition. They believe, moreover, that the incentives of the marketplace are needed to encourage people to work and produce. The opportunities that markets provide mean that some people will be winners and others will lose. These analysts are unconcerned about the distribution of income unless it becomes so unequal that it discourages incentives and reduces efficiency.

Those on the political left argue that public policy should ultimately be guided by human needs. They see personal wealth as being the product of community effort as much as individual effort, and therefore they favor greater government taxation of income and wealth. By and large, European nations have found this argument more compelling than has the United States. This is reflected in the breadth of European social welfare policies. Because there is no correct answer (except possibly keeping distribution away from the extremes), this debate continues.

Causes of Income Inequality

Many factors contribute to income inequality in our society. First, as just mentioned, people are born into different circumstances with differing natural abilities. Families take varying interest in the well-being of their children, with some kids receiving immense inputs of family time and capital, while others receive little. These family choices largely fall outside the realm of public policy.

405

Human Capital The guarantee of a free public education through high school and huge subsidies to public colleges and universities for all Americans are designed to even out some of the economic differences among families. Still, public education does not eliminate the disparities. Some parents plan their children’s education long before they are born, while other parents ignore education altogether.

Table 4 provides evidence of the impact investments in education have on earnings. Those without high school diplomas earned the least, roughly a third less than high school graduates. A college degree resulted in mean earnings about 2.5 times higher than what individuals without high school diplomas earned.

TABLE 4 MEAN EARNINGS BY HIGHEST DEGREE EARNED, 2014
Mean Earnings by Highest Degree
No High School Diploma High School Graduate College Graduate Advanced Degree
All Persons $25,376 $34,736 $57,252 $72,072
Male 26,884 39,052 64,948 84,760
Female 21,268 30,056 50,180 61,620
White 25,636 36,192 58,864 72,280
Black 22,880 30,108 46,540 59,748
Asian 24,804 31,408 59,748 81,224
Hispanic 24,232 30,940 48,724 64,220
Table 15.4: TABLE 4 MEAN EARNINGS BY HIGHEST DEGREE EARNED, 2014

Data from U.S. Census Bureau and Bureau of Labor Statistics.

The U.S. economy has become more technologically complex. Manufacturing jobs have dwindled, reducing the demand for these workers, reducing their real wages. Several decades ago, people with low education levels could find highly productive work in manufacturing, with good wages and benefits. Globalization and increased capital mobility, however, have caused many of these jobs to migrate to lower-wage countries. The result is that real wages have declined for Americans in many manufacturing occupations.

Our economy is increasingly oriented toward service industries, making investments in human capital more important than ever. The service industry spans more than just burger flipping, maid service, and landscaping. The United States is still the world leader in the design and development of new products, basic scientific research and development, and other professional services. All these industries and occupations have one thing in common: the need for highly skilled and highly educated employees.

Other Factors In an earlier chapter, we saw that economic discrimination leads to an income distribution skewed against those subject to discrimination. Reduced wages then reduce an individual’s incentive to invest in human capital because the returns are lower, perpetuating a vicious cycle.

Table 5 outlines some characteristics of households occupying two different income quintiles. By comparing the lowest quintile with the highest, we can see some of the reasons for income inequality. As the Census Bureau summarizes these differences, “High-income households tended to be family households that included two or more earners, lived in the suburbs of a large city, and had a working householder between 35 and 54 years old. In contrast, low-income households tended to be in a city with an elderly householder who lived alone and did not work.”

TABLE 5 DISTRIBUTION OF HOUSEHOLDS BY SELECTED CHARACTERISTICS WITHIN INCOME QUINTILES, 2014
Characteristic Lowest Quintile Highest Quintile
Type of Residence
Inside metropolitan area 81.4% 90.7%
Inside principal city 39.8 30.4
Outside principal city 41.6 60.3
Outside metropolitan area 18.6 9.3
Type of Household
Family households 39.0 86.0
Married-couple families 16.6 77.0
Nonfamily households 61.0 14.0
Householder living alone 57.0 6.8
Age of Householder
15 to 34 years 22.0 15.6
35 to 54 years 26.1 49.7
55 to 64 years 18.1 22.2
65 years or older 33.8 12.5
Number of Earners
No earners 61.5 3.1
One earner 34.2 20.9
Two or more earners 4.4 76.0
Table 15.5: TABLE 5 DISTRIBUTION OF HOUSEHOLDS BY SELECTED CHARACTERISTICS WITHIN INCOME QUINTILES, 2014

Data from U.S. Census Bureau, Current Population Survey, Annual Social and Economic Supplement (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office), 2015.

406

The rise in two-earner households over the last two decades accounts for a large part of the growing inequality in income. Note in Table 5 that only 4.4% of the lowest quintile households had two earners, while 76.0% of the highest quintile did. Also, only 3.1% of top quintile householders did not work, but 61.5% of those in the bottom quintile were not working.

It is hardly surprising that households with two people working tend to have higher incomes than households with only one person or none working. In most households, whether one or two people work represents a choice. Today, clearly more couples are opting for two incomes. This is significant, given that rising income inequality is often cited as evidence that the United States needs to change its public policies to reduce inequalities. Yet, if the rise in inequality is due largely to changes in household attitudes toward work and income, with more couples choosing dual-career households, changes in public policy may not be needed. Rising inequality may simply be a reflection of the changing personal choices of many households.

This overview of income distribution and inequality provides a broad foundation for the remainder of the chapter, which focuses on poverty, its causes, and possible cures.

407

ISSUE

How Much Do You Need to Earn to Be in the Top 1%?

image
DigitalVision Vectors/Getty Images

Among the most contentious issues of the past decade has been the rising income and wealth of the richest Americans. Even during the depths of the Great Recession, average incomes of the richest 1% continued to rise, much to the angst of the rest of the population, many of whom had lost jobs or seen stagnant wages.

Still, the ability to work hard and achieve great wealth is engrained in the hopes of millions who dream to become part of the 1%. And each year, thousands of Americans reach this exclusive group for the first time. How much does one need to earn in order to be included among the top 1%? In 2015 the minimum annual income was approximately $500,000. Although this is a tremendous amount of money, remember that it’s the minimum income required to be in the top 1%. The average income of the top 1% is over $1.3 million per year!

The minimum income to be in the top 1% also varies by state, as shown in the table. In Connecticut, one must earn at least $677,608 to be among the top 1% of income earners, while in Arkansas, it only requires $228,298. Do you think these amounts are unattainable without a rich uncle leaving you millions to jumpstart a lucrative business? Not quite. Only 2 in 5 members of the 1% inherited wealth. The vast majority of those in the 1% are highly educated, motivated individuals who pursue lucrative careers or take chances to build successful businesses. Pursuing a college degree is certainly an important step along the way.

MINIMUM INCOME FOR THE TOP 1% (TOP 5 AND BOTTOM 5 STATES, INCLUDING THE DISTRICT OF COLUMBIA)
1. Connecticut $677,608 47. Mississippi $262,809
2. District of Columbia 555,341 48. Kentucky 262,653
3. New Jersey 538,666 49. West Virginia 242,774
4. Massachusetts 532,328 50. New Mexico 240,847
5. New York 506,051 51. Arkansas 228,298

Data from CNN Money, January 27, 2015.

CHECKPOINT

THE DISTRIBUTION OF INCOME AND WEALTH

  • The functional distribution of income splits income among factors of production.

  • The family or personal distribution of income typically splits income into quintiles.

  • A Lorenz curve cumulates households of various income levels on the horizontal axis and their cumulative share of income on the vertical axis.

  • The Gini coefficient is the ratio of the area between the Lorenz curve and the equal distribution line to the total area below the equal distribution line. It is used to compare income distribution across time and between countries.

  • Income redistribution activities such as progressive taxes, Medicare, Medicaid, and other transfer and welfare programs reduce the Gini coefficient and reduce the inequality in the distribution of income.

  • Income inequality is caused by a number of factors, including individual investment in human capital, natural abilities, and discrimination.

QUESTION: Suppose that a proposal is made to streamline the role of government by reducing the bureaucracy of social income programs. For example, the government would eliminate Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid, and other welfare programs, and instead simply give $10,000 a year to every citizen over the age of 18. Would this improve the income distribution in the United States? Why or why not?

Answers to the Checkpoint questions can be found at the end of this chapter.

Because $10,000 a year per person represents a substantial amount of money to those in the lowest income brackets, it would clearly improve (make more equal) the before-tax and benefits distribution of income. However, many social income programs benefit those with low incomes; for example, those who depend on Social Security and Medicare may be worse off under the proposal, which could make the after-tax and benefits distribution of income worse.